National HR strategies in a global context Luc Soete UNU-MERIT, University of Maastricht The Netherlands OECD/Germany workshop on Advancing Innovation: human resources, education and training, 17-18 November.

Download Report

Transcript National HR strategies in a global context Luc Soete UNU-MERIT, University of Maastricht The Netherlands OECD/Germany workshop on Advancing Innovation: human resources, education and training, 17-18 November.

National HR strategies in a
global context
Luc Soete
UNU-MERIT,
University of Maastricht
The Netherlands
OECD/Germany workshop on Advancing Innovation: human resources, education and training,
17-18 November 2008, Bad Honnef
Outline

Alternative HR models between firms and countries:
underlying reasons

Convergence between the two models of learning
because of globalisation, lessons from Europe

Global international education challenges

Financial crisis and knowledge investments
1. Human Resources and the Knowledge
economy: back to Schumpeter

Useful to start from the old Schumpeterian distinction between the
Schumpeter model I and Schumpeter model II innovation.

Schumpeter I model:


Schumpeter II model:


“Entrepreneurial model”: innovation as the basis of new firm foundation
(ICT, biotechnology); individual inventor-entrepreneur, science based firms,
blue angel/venture capital, importance of exit framework (functioning stock
market, failure tolerance).
“Incremental innovation model”: stepwise innovations based on
continuous accumulation of (tacit) knowledge; role of learning; internal
human resource investments; professionalized R&D labs in large firms.
These two models represent two different models of learning and HR
management within firms and societies.
Dominance of two models in way firms
operate at country aggregate level
Schumpeter I model:
Schumpeter II model:


USA
Canada
Australia
Ireland
Great Britain

Germany
France
Benelux
Scandinavian countries
Austria

China

Japan







With major underlying labour market and
HR differences
Anglo-Saxon model:






Easy hiring and firing
Shorter contracts
Modest unemployment
benefits
Weak trade unions
Labor relations are more
‘conflictuous’
Wage bargaining decentralized
Rhineland (Japan) model:






Protection against firing
Longer stay with same firm
More generous
unemployment benefits
Strong trade unions
Labor relations are more ‘cooperative’
Wage bargaining coordinated and centralized
Reflected in real wages differences
(1960 = 100)
Figure I-1: Development of real wages:
Anglo-Saxon versus Continental-European countries (1960-2004)
400
Real wage (1960=100)
300
200
100
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
Cont.-European
Anglo-Saxon countries: Australia, Canada, New Zealand, UK and USA;
Cont.-European countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy,
Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden;
Source: Database of the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (http://www.ggdc.net/).
1995
Anglo-Saxon
2000
2004
Not in terms of real GDP growth
(1960 = 100)
Figure I-3: Development of real GDP:
Anglo-Saxon versus Continental-European countries (1960-2004)
400
Real GDP (1960=100)
300
200
100
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
Cont.-European
1985
1990
1995
Anglo-Saxon
Anglo-Saxon countries: Australia, Canada, New Zealand, UK and USA;
Cont.-European countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy,
Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden;
Source: Database of the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (http://www.ggdc.net/).
2000
2004
Strongly in labour productivity (value
added per hour worked) (1960 = 100)
Figure I-4: Development of labour productivity:
Anglo-Saxon versus Continental-European countries (1960-2004)
400
Labour productivity (1960=100)
300
200
100
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
Cont.-European
1985
1990
1995
Anglo-Saxon
Anglo-Saxon countries: Australia, Canada, New Zealand, UK and USA;
Cont.-European countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy,
Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden;
Source: Database of the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (http://www.ggdc.net/).
2000
2004
In labour input (working hours)
(1960 = 100)
Figure I-2: Development of total hours worked:
Anglo-Saxon versus Continental-European countries (1960-2004)
200
Total hours worked (1960=100)
180
160
140
120
100
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
Cont.-European
1985
1990
1995
Anglo-Saxon
Anglo-Saxon countries: Australia, Canada, New Zealand, UK and USA;
Cont.-European countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy,
Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden;
Source: Database of the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (http://www.ggdc.net/).
2000
2004
And in capital intensity of production
(capital/output) (1960 = 100)
Traditional reasons for lower labour
productivity growth

Negative effects of flexibilization of the labour market (shorter job duration):

Less loyalty and commitment (firm secrets and technological knowledge can more
easily leak to competitors)

Historical memory of the ‘learning organization’ suffers from frequent changes in
personnel

Manpower training is less attractive (short pay-back period)

Strong growth of management functions for control and monitoring due to loss of
trust and loyalty (frustrating for creative people)

De-centralized wage formation: workers may appropriate part of the monopoly profits
from innovation

Continuous accumulation of incremental knowledge in a Schumpeter II innovation
model is suffering from frequent changes of personnel
2. Knowledge on the move: an industrial
research “past”?

Strong focus on industrial R&D a phenomenon, characteristic of the
industrial revolution.
 Long before going back into the 19th Century, experimental
development work on new or improved products and processes
was carried out in ordinary workshops;
 Technical progress was rapid then but techniques were such that
experience and mechanical ingenuity enabled continued
improvements to be made as result of direct observation and
small-scale experiments and improvements.

Distinctive feature about modern, industrial R&D its scale, its scientific
content and the extent of its professional specialisation
Characteristics of “new” technological
change



Clear shift in the nature of knowledge accumulation: from industrial,
“tight” to more undetermined outcomes, trial and error S&T
Traditional industrial R&D was based on:
 Clearly agreed-upon criteria of progress and ability to evaluate ex
post.
 Ability to “hold in place”, to replicate, to imitate.from laboratory
conditions to industrial production
 A strong cumulative process: learn from natural and deliberate
experiments.
“New” technological change appears more based upon:
 Flexibility, hence difficulty in establishing replication.
 Trial and error elements in research with only “ex post” observed
improvements, difficulty to evaluate.
 Problems of continuously changing external environments: over
time, across sectors, in space.
Users as “innovators”



Particular role of users in the R&D process itself:
 From technically skilled, bèta users (as in workshops) to simplicity
in use
 Underlying process of “democratization” of innovation (Eric von
Hippel)
Particular role of SSH in providing research insights into users:
 not just with respect to industrial research output
 but also in particular with respect to service delivery
 Particular role of ICT with respect to interactive services (ebusiness and e-government)
 European diversity of users comparable to a long tail of
diversification?
SSH research appears essential in many areas of meta social
transformations:
 Knowledge society, sustainable development, mobility, migration,
etc. where “tight” industrial S&T solutions will not do.
Two forms of HR learning

The Schumpeter I model is characterized by the so-called
Science-Technology-Innovation mode of learning (Bengt-Ake
Lundvall), characterised by the dominance of the scienceapproach i.e. formalisation, explicitation and codification

The Schumpeter II model is characterized by Learning by
Doing, Using and Interacting. It refers to more experiencebased, implicitly embedded and embodied knowledge.

The old view of a UK/European ”Paradox” ’Systems with a lot
of good domestic science but less successful in innovation’
reflects by and large focus on STI, neglect of DUI.

Today rather the opposite paradox?
Globalisation HR challenge: a double
change in context

Access to elements from the science base becomes increasingly
important for firms in all sectors – calls for a strengthening of
Schumpeter mode I of dynamics


Entry of new high tech firms (grow or go)
Most firms employ large amounts of personnel with academic/technical
degrees in natural science, engineering, and SSH
 Firms interact more closely with researchers attached to universities or
other public research institutes.

But these changes contribute to accelerating change and callsfor a
strengthening also of the Schumpeter mode II of learning





Interdisciplinary workgroups
Quality circles/groups
Systems for collecting employee proposals from employees
Autonomous groups
Integration of functions
3. European higher education challenges

In the EU, the case could be made that as in the case of trade
diversion, a side effect of economic integration on HE and research
activities within the EU has been intra-European knowledge diversion.

Gradual move from national to European borders: Bologna, ERA, ERC
most easily compared with a research single market with as yet
though very limited mobility, let alone any structural HE institutional
change.

More concentration of research (not more students) needed: 200 US
research universities, how many in Europe? Need for more
differentiation (e.g. focus on graduate students) amongst higher
education establishments

Increased autonomy and selectivity in admissions (US and Asian
examples), more inter-disciplinarity, changing mindset of students and
staff, more flexible employment regime
Schumpeterian HE challenges

Need for reform in European HE system in direction of
excellence (cost of social cohesion), specialisation, mobility
alongside the lines of the Schumpeter mode I view

At the same time and at both research and HE level, Europe has
many high quality large multilateral research and post-graduate
research organisations: CERN, ESA, EMBL…, and national
organisations: CEA, Max Planck Gesellschaft, TNO, IMEC,
Fraunhofer

Little cross-country learning of the Schumpeter mode II sort
often because of lack of critical mass, few mergers

Schumpeter mode II learning based on strong localised
learning features with links to universities and regional “smart
specialisation” based on particularisation
4. Current financial crisis: Short term
impact on R&D

The current financial crisis is likely to influence private R&D
investments in a number of ways:
 The negative impact on profitability leads to a focus on most
innovative segments of production at the expense of lower value
added segments;
 Within the R&D portfolio, focus will be on most promising
development areas at the expense of longer term, more risky
projects.
 At employment level, likely to be labour hoarding in R&D; firing of
flexible temporrary employment in production

Paradoxically, the deeper the recession, the more likely Europe and
the Netherlands might be coming nearer to the 3% R&D/GDP target in
2010!
Longer term impacts: outsourcing

In the longer term though, a renewed focus on possibilities of
increased international and domestic outsourcing of R&D so as
to further reduce R&D costs



More outsourcing of development parts to cheaper
locations
Outsourcing of existing private R&D infrastructure to
local/national authorities as common, public “open
innovation infrastructure”
Increasing amount of basic R&D activities outsourced to
(porfessional) universities
Onshoring and smart specialisation

Distinction between public and private R&D investments
becomes less relevant, search is on for synergies:

Offshoring from private to public, public private partnerships
between universities, (semi-)public research institutions, private
firms
 Onshoring from private and public: attracted by similar locational
facilities

Emergence of smart specialisation clusters:


:
From a research perspective globally linked and networked,
From a financial perspective based on smart investment in
locational infrastructures acting as physical attractor for
onshoring of R&D activities.
A new Global Knowledge Keynesianism?

The current “fire prevention” of governments in financial institutions,
with the temporary (partial) nationalisation of large national banks,
raises questions about stronger local financial involvement in
knowledge investments:

Could the new financial “nationalism” in Europe be considered an
anchorage instrument for the localisation of international knowledge

In HE, international outsourcing and twinning with Southern partners
as new form of more organisationally embedded international
partnership
 Imagine… about 50 universities and professional universities in
the Netherlands, about a similar number of research institutes
 Formal twinning will need to be coordinated by whom?
 True internationalisation of research and higher education
“Recherche sans frontière”

Global research issues should become fully integrated in all applied research
and HE in the developed world. Become core part of research and higher
education institutions within an open research without borders environment..

At HE level integration in curricula and research activities of university and
high school departments of global challenges

At research level, global development involves broadening the scope of
research activities to include more systematically all users groups (BoP), and
in particular various communities of practice. Involvement of those groups
appears increasingly essential for successful innovation.

Particularly with respect to applied research, including design, the possibilities
of such collaborative innovation processes will have to involve much stronger
collaboration, interactions, and partnerships with research communities in
developing countries.