Options Global Financial Management Campbell R. Harvey Fuqua School of Business Duke University [email protected] http://www.duke.edu/~charvey Overview Options: » Uses, definitions, types Put-Call Parity » Futures and Forwards Valuation » Binomial » Black Scholes Applications »
Download ReportTranscript Options Global Financial Management Campbell R. Harvey Fuqua School of Business Duke University [email protected] http://www.duke.edu/~charvey Overview Options: » Uses, definitions, types Put-Call Parity » Futures and Forwards Valuation » Binomial » Black Scholes Applications »
Options Global Financial Management
Campbell R. Harvey Fuqua School of Business Duke University [email protected]
http://www.duke.edu/~charvey 1
Overview
Options: » Uses, definitions, types Put-Call Parity » Futures and Forwards Valuation » Binomial » Black Scholes Applications » Portfolio Insurance » Hedging 2
Definitions
Call Option
is a right (but not an obligation) to
buy
an asset at a pre arranged price (=exercise price) on or until a pre-arranged date (=maturity).
Put Option
is a right (but not an obligation) to
sell
an asset at a pre arranged price (=exercise price) on or until a pre-arranged date (=maturity).
European Options
can be exercised at maturity only.
American Options
can be exercised at any time before maturity 3
Examples of Options
Securities
Equity options Warrants Underwriting Call provisions Convertible bonds Caps Interest rate options Insurance Loan guarantees Risky bonds Equity
Real Options
Options to expand Abandonment options Options to delay investment Model sequences
Options are everywhere!
4
Payoff
Values of Options at Expiry
Buying a Call
Buy Call Option
Payoff = max[0, S T - X] 0 X Stock Price 5
Payoff
Values of Options at Expiry
Writing a Call
Sell Call Option
Payoff = - max[0, S T - X] X 0 Stock Price 6
Payoff
Values of Options at Expiry
Buying a Put
Buy Put Option
Payoff = max[0, X - S T ] X 0 X Stock Price 7
Values of Options at Expiry
Selling a Put Payoff
Sell Put Option
Payoff = - max[0, X - S T ] X 0 Stock Price -X 8
Example
What are the payoffs to the buyer of a call option and a put option if the exercise price is X=$50?
Stock Price 20 Buy Call Write Call 0 0 Buy Put Write Put 30 -30 40 0 0 10 -10 60 80 10 30 -10 -30 0 0 0 0 9
Valuation of Options: Put-Call Parity
Principle: » Construct two portfolios » Show they have the same payoffs » Conclude they must cost the same
Portfolio I
: Buy a share of stock today for a price of S 0 simultaneously borrowed an amount of PV(X)=Xe -rT .
and » How much would your portfolio be worth at the end of T years? – Assume that the stock does not pay a dividend.
Position
Buy Stock Borrow Portfolio I
0
-S 0 PV(X) PV(X) - S 0 S T
T
S T -X - X 10
Payoff
Payoff of Portfolio I
Payoff on Stock S T S T - X Net Payoff 0 X Stock Price Payoff on Borrowing -X 11
Put-Call Parity
Portfolio II:
Buy a call option and sell a put option with a maturity date of T and an exercise price of X. How much will your options be worth at the end of T years?
Position
Buy Call Sell Put Net Position
0
-C E P E P E -C E
T
max[0,S T -max[0,X-S T ] S T - X -X] Since the two portfolios have the same payoffs at date T, they must have the same price today.
The
put-call parity
relationship is: C E - P E = S 0 - PV(X) This implies:
Call - Put = Stock - Bond
12
Payoff 0 -X
Put-Call Parity
Payoff on long call X S T - X Net Payoff Stock Price Payoff on short put 13
Put-Call Parity and Arbitrage
A stock is currently selling for $100. A call option with an exercise price of $90 and maturity of 3 months has a price of $12. A put option with an exercise price of $90 and maturity of 3 months has a price of $2. The one-year T-bill rate is 5.0%. Is there an arbitrage opportunity available in these prices? From Put-Call Parity, the price of the call option should be equal to: » C E = P E + S 0 - Xe -rT =$13.12
Since the market price of the call is $12, it is underpriced by $1.12. We would want to buy the call, sell the put, sell the stock, and invest PV($90)= 88.88 for 3 months. 14
Put-Call Parity and Arbitrage
The cash flows for this investment are outlined below:
Position
Buy call Sell put Sell stock Buy T-bill
Net Position 0
-12.00
2.00
100.00
-90e -(0.05)0.25
1.12
S T
0 S T -90 -S T 90
0 S T >X
S T -90 0 -S T 90
0
Hence, realize an arbitrage profit of 1.12
» This is independent of the value of the stock price!
15
Options and Futures
Compare this with a futures contract that specicifies that you buy a stock at
X
at time
T
. The futures contract trades today at F 0 .
» What is the price of the futures if there is no arbitrage?
– Construct zero-payoff portfolio: Buy a Put, Write a Call, and buy the futures contract
Position
Write Call Buy Put Buy Futures
0
C E -P E -F 0 C E -P E -F 0
T
-Max[0,S T - X] Max[0,S T - X] S T - X 0
F
0
C E
P E
16
Payoff 0 X
Options and Futures
Payoff on long call S T - X Payoff on Future X Payoff on short put Stock Price Call is
right
to purchase Short Put is
obligation
to sell Future combines both When is F 0 =0?
17
Debt and Equity as Options
Suppose a firm has debt with a face value of $1m outstanding that matures at the end of the year. What is the value of debt and equity at the end of the year?
Asset Value 0.3m
Payoff to Shareholders 0 Payoff to Debtholders 0.3m
0.6m
0.9m
0 0 0.6m
0.9m
1.2m
1.5m
0.2m
0.5m
1.0m
1.0m
18
Debt and Equity
Consider a firm with zero coupon debt outstanding with a face value of F. The debt will come due in exactly one year.
The payoff to the equityholders of this firm one year from now will be the following: Payoff to Equity = max[0, V-F] where V is the total value of the firm ’ s assets one year from now.
Similarly, the payoff to the firm ’ s bondholders one year from now will be: Payoff to Bondholders = V - max[0,V-F]
Equity
has a payoff like that on a
call option
.
Risky debt
has a payoff that is equal to the total value of the firm,
less
the payoff on a
call option
.
19
Payoffs
Debt and Equity
Equityholders Bondholders 0 F Firm Value 20
Valuing Options
Establish bounds for Options Upper bound on European call: » Compare to following portfolio: buy one share, borrow PV of exercise price » Consider value at maturity: S
E
>S-PV(X) before maturity 21
S, C C=S
Bounds on Option Values
CE>S-PV(X); dominates portfolio of stock and borrowing X.
Example on Option Bounds I
Suppose a stock is selling for $50 per share. The riskfree interest rate is 8%. A call option with an exercise price of $50 and 6 months to maturity is selling for $1.50. Is there an arbitrage opportunity available?
» C E > max[ 0, S 0 - Xe -rT ] » C E > max[ 0, 50 - 50e -(0.08)0.5 ] = 1.96
Since the price is only $1.50, the call is
underpriced
by
at least
$0.46.
Position
Buy call Sell stock Buy T-bill
Net Postion 0
-1.50
50 -50e -(0.08)0.5
0.46
S T
0 -S T 50
50-S T >0 S T >X
S T -50 -S T 50
0
23
Example on Option Bounds II
Now suppose you observe a put option with an exercise price of $55 and 6 months to maturity selling for $2.50. Does this represent an arbitrage opportunity?
» P E > max[ 0, Xe -rT - S 0 ] » P E > max[ 0, 55e -(0.08)0.5 - 50] = 2.84
Since the price is only $2.50, the put is
underpriced
by
at least
$0.34
Position
Buy put Buy stock Borrow
Net Postion 0
-2.50
-50 55e -(0.08)0.5
0.34
S T
55-S T S T -55
0 S T >X
0 S T -55
S T -55>0
24
Valuing Options as Contingent Claims
Idea:
Investors attach different values to
states
in which assets pay off: $1 is worth more in bad times than in good times.
Values depend on preferences for insuring against bad times and discounting (time value of money).
Value of $1 in good times or bad times (or a continuum of states) can be inferred from prices of stocks and bonds.
125 High State Stock Price = 100 r=10% 80 Low State
Procedure:
» Determine value of $1 in good and in bad state » Use the value to infer the value of the option 25
Pricing Contingent Claims
Step 1: Determine the value of states
Method
Break up payment to shareholders into two components: » Shareholders receive at least 80 for sure (in good
and
bad state).
» Shareholders receive an additional 45 if the share price is high, otherwise nothing.
Steps:
1. The present value of a safe payment of 80 is simply: 80 2. The value shareholders attach to the uncertain 45=125-80 must be the difference between the current share price and the value of the safe payment: 100 - 72.73 = 27.27
3. The present value of $1 in the good state is 27.27/45=0.606.
26
Pricing Contingent Claims
Step 2: Value an Option Consider the following option: Maturity: Exercise price: Type: Option Value = ?
1 year 110 European 15 How does the option value develop?
0 High State Low State 27
Why does this work?
Contingent Claim Pricing and Arbitrage Compare two portfolios:
Portfolio 1:
1 Call option Asset/State Stock Price = 80 Stock Price = 125
Portfolio 2:
1/3 share; 1 loan which pays off 80/3 at the end Loan -80/3 -80/3 Call Option Portfolio 1 Portfolio 2 0 0 0 15 15 15 $100 3 $80 / 3 $9.
09 28
Arbitrage: The General Idea
General Rule:
Use arbitrage principle by constructing portfolio with same payoffs as option (this is called
replication
).
1 lowest value of the delta shares. delta is called the
option delta
: If portfolio replicates option, then it must have the same value as the option.
Implications:
29
Options with Many States
Suppose there are more than two possible states at the end of the period. Then: subdivide period.
Example:
3 states at the end of the period: Divide movement into two 117 100 periods with two-states in each.
85
Solution:
Value the option for each of the mid-period nodes and then fold it backwards into the first node.
Repeat this for ever smaller intervals to cover larger numbers of states.
137 100 73 30
The Black-Scholes Formula
Alternative Solution:
Repeat the above process until infinity; Continuum of different states.
Use mathematical theory to determine result of this process.
d
1
d
2 Option value= ln
d
1
T
[delta
x
2
T
share price]
N(d 1 ) x P
-
-
[bank loan]
N(d 2 ) x PV(X)
31
Call Option Sensitivities
The Option Pricing formula gives the following sensitivies for a call option:
Increase In:
S T r X
Effect on Call Price
32
Intuition for Black-Scholes
C
0
e
e
T
|
X
Pr
S T T
X
X
Pr
S T
X
e
C
0
e
e
*
T
|
T
X X
Pr *
S T
X
Pr *
S T
X T
|
T
X
Pr *
S
T
X
S
N 1 Pr *
S
T
X
N 2 33
Black-Scholes Put Option Formula
We can use the put-call parity relationship to derive the Black-Scholes put option formula:
P
E
= C
E
- S + Xe
-rT Use Put-Call Parity and the fact that the normal distribution is symmetric around the mean:
P
E
= -SN(-d
1
) + Xe
-rT
N(-d
2
)
34
Put Option Sensitivities
The Option Pricing formula gives the following sensitivies for a put option:
Increase In:
S T r X
Effect on Put Price
35
Example
On February 2, 1996, Microsoft stock closed at a price of $93 per share. » Annual standard deviation is about 32%.
» The one-year T-bill rate is 4.82%. What are the Black-Scholes prices for both calls and puts with: » An exercise price of $100 and » a maturity of April 1996 (77 days)?
» How do these prices compare to the actual market prices of these options?
36
How to Use Black-Scholes
The inputs for the Black-Scholes formula are: » S = $93.00 s » X = $100.00 s r = 4.82% = 32% » T = 77/365 This gives: d 1 = -0.351
d 2 = -0.498.
The cumulative normal density for these values are N(d 1 ) = 0.3628
N(d 2 ) = 0.3103.
Plugging these values into the Black-Scholes formula gives: c = $3.02
p = $9.02.
37
How to Use Black-Scholes
Microsoft Put and Call Options
Option
Apr. call 100 Apr. put 100
B-S Prices
$3.02
$9.02
Actual Prices
$3.25
$9.125
38
Implied Volatility
39
Implied Volatilities
It is common for traders to quote prices in terms of implied volatilities.
This is the volatility ( ) that sets the Black-Scholes price equal to the market price.
This can be computed using SOLVER in EXCEL.
40
Applications of Options I:
Volatility Bets Suppose you have no information about the return of the stock, but you believe that the market
underrates
the volatility of the stock: » Give an example!
– How can you trade?
Buy
Straddle:
» Buy a call and a put on the same stock – same exercise price – same time to maturity..
41
Payoff
Option Trading Strategies: The Straddle
X 0 Put Payoff Straddle Payoff X Call Payoff Stock Price 42
Hedging with Options
Initial investment (option premium) is required You eliminate downside risks, while retaining upside potential
Example
» It is the end of August and we will receive 1m DM at the end of October.
» At this point, we will
sell
DM, converting them back into dollars.
» We are concerned about the price at which we will be able to sell DM.
» We can lock in a minimum sale price by
buying put options
.
– Since the total exposure is for 1m DM and each contract is for 62,500 DM we buy 16 put option contracts.
– Suppose we choose the puts struck at 0.66 - locking in a lower bound of 0.66 $/DM.
43
Heding with Currency Options
Scenario I:
Deutschmark falls to $0.30
We have the right to sell 1m DM for $0.66 each by exercising the put options.
Since DM ’ s are only worth $0.30 each we
do
choose to exercise.
Our cash inflow is therefore $660,000
Scenario II:
Deutschemark rises to $0.90
We have the right to sell 1m DM for $0.66 each by exercising the put options.
Since DM ’ s are worth $0.90 each we
do not
choose to exercise.
We sell the DM on the open market for $0.90 each.
Our cash inflow is therefore $900,000 44
Portfolio Insurance
Reconsider the case of a fund manager who wishes to insure his portfolio 45
Summary
Options are derivative securities: » Replicate payoffs with combinations of underlying assets Put and Call prices are linked Valuation as contingent claims » Use Black-Scholes as approximation Value of option increases with volatility of underlying assets Use options for » Volatility bets » Portfolio Insurance » Hedging 46