Transcript Document
The Return to Soft Dollar Pegging
in East Asia
Mitigating Conflicted Virtue
Ronald McKinnon
Stanford University
and
Gunther Schnabl
Tübingen University
October 2004
The Exchange Rate Debate in the 1990s
Before 1997, East Asian countries, except for Japan, “softly” pegged
their exchange rates to the U.S. dollar.
1997-98 Crisis: Thailand, Indonesia, Philippines, Korea, and Malaysia
are attacked and devalue—with bankruptcies and economic
downturns spreading contagiously.
The IMF blames the soft pegging for encouraging over borrowing and
current account deficits leading unsustainable dollar and yen
debts. It warns against any return to dollar pegging.
Williamson (2000), Kawai (2002), Ogawa and Ito (2002)—suggest
weighting the Japanese yen more heavily in the currency baskets
of the smaller East Asian economies in the face of wide
fluctuations in the yen/dollar rate.
The Debate In the New Millennium
By 2004, the East Asian “crisis” and non crisis economies had
returned to soft dollar pegging. China and Hong Kong retained
hard pegs through the crisis, and Malaysia pegged in Sept 1998 at
3.8 ringgit per dollar. Even the yen/dollar rate is more stable.
But now all East Asian countries run large current account
surpluses—even with net inflows of FDI (China). Only massive
foreign official interventions kept their exchange rates from
appreciating in 2003 and early 2004
Influential articles by Dooley, Folkerts-Landau, and Garber (2003)(2004) argue that East Asian countries on the dollar’s “periphery”
are deliberately undervaluing their currencies to stimulate exports
to the U.S. at the “center” to promote development.
Intensified pressure from the IMF, the G-7, and the U.S. Treasury, for
China to appreciate: “There should be more flexible currencies,
not only for China but the whole of Asia” Rodrigo de Rato, IMF
Managing Director, 29 Sept 2004 at IMF-World Bank Meetings in
Washington.
This Paper and McKinnon Book (2005)
The Case for Asian Dollar Pegs
East
Asian economies
Have sufficient fiscal and monetary control to
target exchange rates, but have more difficulty
targeting domestic inflation independently.
Are becoming highly integrated economically
with more than 50% of trade with each other.
They need stable cross rates of exchange.
Debtor countries have “original sin” and
creditors have “conflicted virtue” making
foreign exchange risks more difficult to hedge.
The Rise of Intra Regional Trade in East Asia,
1980-2002 (share of total exports)
Exports
50
Percentage
40
1980
30
1990
20
2002
10
0
Intra East Asia
United States
Rest of the World
East Asia: China, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore,
Taiwan, and Thailand
The Rise of Intra Regional Trade in East Asia,
1980-2002 (share of total imports)
Imports
60
Percentage
50
40
1980
1990
30
2002
20
10
0
Intra East Asia
United States
Rest of the World
East Asia: China, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore,
Taiwan, and Thailand
Figure 1: East Asian Exchange Rate Pegs
against the Dollar, 1980:01-2004:04 (Monthly)
Chinese Yuan
Hong Kong Dollar
800
700
700
600
600
500
500
400
400
300
300
200
200
100
800
Singapore Dollar
700
700
600
600
500
500
400
400
300
300
200
200
100
100
0
1980.011983.011986.011989.01 1992.011995.011998.012001.012004.01
1
1
04
.0
20
1
01
.0
20
98
.0
1
19
1
95
.0
19
1
92
.0
19
1
86
.0
89
.0
19
19
800
19
1
1
0
19
0
1980.01 1983.01 1986.01 1989.01 1992.01 1995.01 1998.01 2001.01 2004.01
80
.0
100
83
.0
800
Taiwan Dollar
0
1980.01 1983.01 1986.01 1989.01 1992.01 1995.01 1998.01 2001.01 2004.01
Figure 1 (Continued) Crisis Economies,
1980:01-2004:04 (Monthly)
Korean Won
Indonesian Rupiah
2500
2000
1500
1000
800
800
700
700
600
600
500
500
400
400
300
300
200
200
500
100
100
0
1980.011983.011986.011989.011992.011995.011998.012001.012004.01
0
1980.011983.011986.011989.011992.011995.011998.012001.012004.01
Philippine Peso
Thai Baht
800
800
700
700
600
600
500
500
400
400
300
300
200
200
100
100
0
1980.01 1983.01 1986.01 1989.01 1992.01 1995.01 1998.01 2001.01 2004.01
Malaysian Ringgit
0
1980.01 1983.01 1986.01 1989.01 1992.01 1995.01 1998.01 2001.01 2004.01
0
1980.01 1983.01 1986.01 1989.01 1992.01 1995.01 1998.01 2001.01 2004.01
Frankel and Wei Regression (1994)
eEastAsiancurrencySwissfranc t
1 2eDollarSwis sfranc t 3eYenSwissfr anct 4eMarkSwissf ranc t ut
Problem: For any one East Asian currency other than
Japan, how do you measure the weight of each major
currency—the dollar, yen, or euro—in its currency
“basket”?
Answer: Choose an outside currency as numeraire,
e.g., the Swiss Franc, to measure all exchange rates
in the above regression.
Figure 2: Dollar’s Weight in East Asian Currency
Baskets, 130-Trading-Day Rolling Regressions,
1990:01-2004:05 (Daily)
Chinese Yuan
Hong Kong Dollar
1.6
1.6
1.4
1.4
1.2
1.2
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
0.0
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
Singapore Dollar
Taiwan Dollar
1.6
1.6
1.4
1.4
1.2
1.2
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
0.0
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
Figure 2 (Continued), Dollar’s Weight in East
Asian Currency Baskets Crisis Economy,
1990:01-2004:05 (Daily)
Indonesian Rupiah
Korean Won
Malaysian Ringgit
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.0
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.2
0.0
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
0.0
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
0.0
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
Philippine Peso
Thai Baht
1.6
1.6
1.4
1.4
1.2
1.2
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
0.0
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
Figure 3: Exchange Rate Volatility against the US
Dollar of Selected Crisis and Non-Crisis Currencies,
1990:01-2004:05 (Daily)
Chinese Yuan
Hong Kong Dollar
Thai Baht
8%
8%
8%
6%
6%
6%
4%
4%
4%
2%
2%
2%
0%
0%
0%
-2%
-2%
-2%
-4%
-4%
-4%
-6%
-6%
-6%
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
Malaysian Ringgit
Philippine Peso
Japanese Yen
8%
8%
8%
6%
6%
6%
4%
4%
4%
2%
2%
2%
0%
0%
0%
-2%
-2%
-2%
-4%
-4%
-4%
-6%
-6%
-6%
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
Figure 3 (Continued), Exchange Rate Volatility
against the US Dollar, 1990:01-2004:05 (Daily)
Indonesian Rupiah
Korean Won
Euro (German Mark)
8%
8%
6%
6%
6%
4%
4%
4%
2%
2%
2%
0%
0%
0%
-2%
-2%
-2%
-4%
-4%
-4%
-6%
-6%
-6%
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
Singapore Dollar
8%
8%
8%
New Taiwan Dollar
8%
Swiss Franc
6%
6%
4%
4%
2%
2%
0%
0%
-2%
-2%
-4%
-4%
-4%
-6%
-6%
-6%
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
-8%
01.01.1990 01.01.1993 01.01.1996 01.01.1999 01.01.2002
6%
4%
2%
0%
-2%
Table 1: Standard Deviations of Daily
Exchange Rate Fluctuations against the Dollar
Pre-crisis
Crisis
Post-crisis
2003/2004
Chinese Yuan
0.03
0.01
0.00
0.00
Hong Kong Dollar
0.02
0.03
0.03
0.05
Indonesian Rupiah
0.17
4.43
1.11
0.43
Korean Won
0.22
2.35
0.43
0.43
Malaysian Ringgit
0.25
1.53
0.00
0.00
Philippine Peso
0.37
1.31
0.51
0.25
Singapore Dollar
0.20
0.75
0.27
0.29
New Taiwan Dollar
0.19
0.50
0.21
0.20
Thai Baht
0.21
1.55
0.38
0.27
Japanese Yen
0.67
1.00
0.64
0.57
Euro (Deutsche Mark)
0.60
0.58
0.64
0.64
Swiss Franc
0.69
0.66
0.66
0.70
Data source: Datastream. Percent changes. Pre-crisis = 02/01/94 – 05/30/97, crisis = 06/01/97
– 12/31/98, post-crisis = 01/01/99 – 05/17/04, 2003/2004 = 01/01/03 – 05/17/04.
Table 2: Standard Deviations of Monthly
Exchange Rate Fluctuations against the Dollar
Pre-crisis
Crisis
Post-crisis
Chinese Yuan
0.25
0.03
0.00
Hong Kong Dollar
0.08
0.07
0.11
Indonesian Rupiah
0.26
26.54
5.16
Korean Won
1.01
11.53
1.92
Malaysian Ringgit
1.06
6.69
0.00
Philippine Peso
1.19
5.25
1.67
Singapore Dollar
0.76
2.88
1.18
New Taiwan Dollar
1.01
2.63
1.35
Thai Baht
0.43
8.88
1.60
Japanese Yen
3.66
3.64
2.39
Euro (Deutsche Mark)
2.20
2.33
2.58
Swiss Franc
2.62
2.60
2.54
Data source: IMF: IFS.
Figure 4: Exchange Rate Changes
against the US dollar 1999:01-2001:12
0.00%
5.00%
10.00%
15.00%
20.00%
25.00%
30.00%
35.00%
Chinese Yuan
Hong Kong Dollar
Indonesian Rupiah
Korean Won
Malaysian Ringgit
Philippine Peso
Singapore Dollar
New Taiwan Dollar
Thai Baht
Japanese Yen
Euro
Swiss Franc
Data source: IMF: IFS.
depreciation
40.00%
Figure 5: Exchange Rate Changes
against the US dollar 2002:01-2004:04
-30.00%
-25.00%
-20.00%
-15.00%
-10.00%
-5.00%
0.00%
Chinese Yuan
Hong Kong Dollar
Indonesian Rupiah
Korean Won
Malaysian Ringgit
Philippine Peso
appreciation
Singapore Dollar
New Taiwan Dollar
Thai Baht
Japanese Yen
Euro
Swiss Franc
Data source: IMF: IFS.
5.00%
10.00%
15.00%
Figure 6: Official Foreign Exchange Reserves of
Crisis and Non-Crisis Countries in Millions of
Dollars, 1980:01-2004:04 (Monthly)
China
Hong Kong
280000
120000
240000
100000
Thailand
40000
35000
30000
200000
80000
25000
160000
60000
20000
120000
15000
40000
80000
10000
20000
40000
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
Malaysia
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
Philippines
40000
16000
35000
14000
30000
12000
25000
10000
20000
8000
15000
6000
10000
4000
5000
2000
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
5000
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
Germany
120000
100000
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
Figure 6 (Continued), Official Foreign
Exchange Reserves, 1980:01-2004:04 (Monthly)
Indonesia
32000
28000
24000
20000
16000
12000
8000
4000
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
Singapore
90000
Korea
130000
120000
110000
100000
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
180000
80000
160000
70000
140000
60000
120000
50000
100000
40000
80000
30000
60000
20000
40000
10000
20000
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
Taiwan
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
Japan
500000
450000
400000
350000
300000
250000
200000
150000
100000
50000
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
60000
US
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
1980:01 1984:01 1988:01 1992:01 1996:01 2000:01
Dollar dominance in East Asia
Original sin
Underdeveloped domestic bond market or in some
cases developed domestic bond market (India)
Debtors cannot borrow in own currency nor can they
hedge their net dollar indebtedness.
Currency mismatch and maturity mismatch.
[Eichengreen and Hausmann 1999, Hausmann and Panizza 2003]
Conflicted virtue
Creditors cannot lend in their own currencies nor can
they hedge their net dollar assets.
Currency mismatch but no necessary maturity
mismatch [McKinnon and Schnabl 2004, McKinnon 2005]
Conflicted virtue
High-saving countries lend to foreigners in the
form of current account surpluses. However, as
the stock of dollar claims cumulates:
Foreigners start complaining that the country’s ongoing
flow of trade surpluses is unfair and the result of having
an undervalued currency.
Domestic holders of dollar assets worry more about a
self-sustaining run into the domestic currency forcing
an appreciation.
Conflicted virtue:
To appreciate or not to appreciate
As runs into the domestic
currency out of dollars
begin, the government is
“conflicted” because
(repetitive) appreciation
could set in train serious
deflation ending with a
zero interest liquidity trap
(Japan)
But failure to appreciate
could elicit trade
sanctions from foreigners.
A “free” float becomes an
indefinite upward spiral
The story of Japan (I)
There were repetitive appreciations of yen from
1970s to mid-’90s under mercantile pressure
from trade partners―particularly the United
States, but trade surpluses continued to
cumulate.
Reason:
Exchange rate changes only determine domestic
inflation or deflation, not trade balance. The simpleminded elasticities approach is invalid in financially
open economies. [McKinnon and Ohno 1997]
Do exchange rate changes necessarily
bring BoP balance?
Elasticity model
BoP balance through current
account changes if Marshall-Lerner
condition holds.
McKinnon and Ohno in Dollar
and Yen (1997):
Inflationary/deflationary pressure
only.
Indeterminate CA effect in the
short term because of domestic
absorption effect.
The story of Japan (II)
Negative risk premium
[Goyal and McKinnon 2003]
To maintain portfolio balance, Japanese
financial institutions demand a higher
return on dollars (which is riskier given the
volatility in exchange rate).
The internationally determined dollar asset
return thus pushes down the yen interest
rate. It finally forced Japan into the the
zero interest liquidity trap by the end of
1996.
Is China like Japan?
China has a big advantage over Japan:
The RMB exchange rate has been and can be
more credibly maintained at the current level
without disturbing domestic price level.
And a disadvantage:
China’s net FDI inflows are much larger than
Japan’s. FDI can be seen as illiquid liabilities
but imposes liquid dollar claims.
Table 3: East Asian Current Accounts in
Comparison to the U.S., 1990-2003
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
Percent of GDP
Japan
1.5
2.0
3.0
3.0
2.7
2.1
1.4
2.3
3.0
2.6
2.5
2.1
2.8
3.2
Singapore
8.5
11.3
11.9
7.2
16.2
17.7
15.2
15.6
22.6
18.6
14.5
19.0
21.5
30.9
Taiwan
7.0
7.1
4.1
3.1
2.7
2.1
3.9
2.4
1.3
2.8
2.9
6.4
9.1
10.0
Indonesia
-2.6
-3.3
-2.0
-1.3
-1.6
-3.2
-3.4
-2.3
4.3
4.1
5.3
4.9
4.5
3.9
Korea
-0.8
-2.8
-1.3
0.3
-1.0
-1.7
-4.4
-1.7
12.7
6.0
2.7
1.9
1.3
2.0
Malaysia
-2.0
-8.5
-3.7
-4.5
-6.1
-9.7
-4.4
-5.9
13.2
15.9
9.4
8.3
7.6
11.1
Philippines
-6.1
-2.3
-1.9
-5.6
-4.6
-2.7
-4.8
-5.3
2.4
9.5
8.2
1.8
5.4
2.1
Thailand
-8.5
-7.7
-5.7
-5.1
-5.6
-8.1
-8.1
-2.0
12.7
10.1
7.6
5.4
6.1
5.6
China
3.1
3.3
1.4
0.0
1.3
0.2
0.9
4.1
3.3
2.1
1.9
1.5
2.9
2.1
1.5
6.4
4.3
6.1
8.5
11.0
-2.3
-3.1
-4.2
-3.9
-4.6
-4.9
Hong Kong
United States
-1.4
0.1
-0.8
-1.2
-1.7
-1.4
-1.5
-1.5
Billions of US Dollars
Total East
Asia
54.5
73.8
117.5
117.8
132.9
93.8
44.2
129.4
244.5
231.7
213.7
179.1
238.9
255.2
Total US
-79.0
3.7
-48.0
-82.0
117.7
105.2
117.2
127.7
204.7
290.9
411.5
393.7
480.9
541.8
Data source: IMF: IFS.
Figure 7: International Investment
Position of Japan (Billions of Dollars)
1600
total
public
private
1400
billions of dollars
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
1980
-200
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
Source: Japan: Ministry of Finance.
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
Figure 8: Interest Rates in the US and Japan,
Long-Term: 10-Year US Treasuries and JGBs,
1980-2004
16
14
Japan
US
percent per annum
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1980M1
1983M1
1986M1
1989M1
1992M1
1995M1
1998M1
2001M1
2004M1
Figure 8: Interest Rates in the US and Japan,
Short-Term: Money Market Rates , 1980-2004
20
18
Japan (call money rate)
US (federal funds rate)
16
percent per annum
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1980M1
1983M1
1986M1
1989M1
1992M1
1995M1
1998M1
2001M1
2004M1
Implications for Interest Rates:
The Negative Risk Premium
To sustain the interest differential between yen and dollar
assets, consider an augmented interest parity relationship:
i = i* + se +
where i is the (endogenously determined) Japanese longterm nominal interest rate, i* is the (exogenously given)
US long-term nominal interest rate, s is the yen price of
one dollar, se is expected depreciation of the yen, and is
the risk premium on yen assets.
From the 70s to the mid 90s, the interest differential, i – i*,
was driven primarily by the negative se term when the
erratically appreciating yen peaked out in April 1995. Since
the mid-90s, se 0 and the interest differential has been
driven primarily by the term, which is also negative
(Goyal and McKinnon 2003).
Figure 9: Money Market Interest
Rates 1990:01-2004:01 (Monthly)
China (Bank Rate)
Hong Kong
16
12
14
10
China
United States
8
12
Hong Kong
United States
10
6
8
6
4
4
2
2
0
1990M1
1992M1
1994M1
1996M1
1998M1
2000M1
2002M1
2004M1
1992M1
1994M1
1996M1
14
Singapore
10
0
1990M1
1998M1
2000M1
2002M1
2004M1
Taiwan
12
9
Singapore
United States
8
Taiwan
United States
10
7
8
6
5
6
4
4
3
2
2
1
0
1990M1
1992M1
1994M1
1996M1
1998M1
2000M1
2002M1
2004M1
0
1990M1
1992M1
1994M1
1996M1
1998M1
2000M1
2002M1
2004M1
Figure 9 (Continued), Money Market
Interest Rates 1990:01-2004:01 (Monthly)
Indonesia
90
Korea
25
Malaysia
12
80
10
70
20
Indonesia
Singapore
60
Malaysia
United States
Korea
United States
8
15
50
6
40
10
30
4
20
5
2
10
0
1990M1
1992M1
1994M1
1996M1
1998M1
2000M1
2002M1
2004M1
0
1990M1
1992M1
1994M1
Philippines
30
1996M1
1998M1
2000M1
2002M1
2004M1
Thailand
25
25
20
Philippines
United States
20
Thailand
United States
15
15
10
10
5
5
0
1990M1
1992M1
1994M1
1996M1
1998M1
2000M1
2002M1
2004M1
0
1990M1
1992M1
1994M1
1996M1
1998M1
2000M1
2002M1
2004M1
0
1990M1
1992M1
1994M1
1996M1
1998M1
2000M1
2002M1
2004M1
Interest Differentials, Portfolio Balance,
and the Impossibility Free Floating
As dollar claims accumulate, a sufficiently large
interest differential to induce private portfolio
holdings of dollars becomes unsustainable—as in
Japan when yen interest rates approach zero.
The problem worsens when US interest rates are
unusually low, as in 2003-04.
Then, increasing official foreign exchange
reserves become the dominant mode of financing
Asian current account surpluses.
And the private unwillingness to hold dollars
makes a free float impossible.
Table 4: East Asian Current Accounts (CA)
and Changes in Foreign Reserves (RC)
Billions of
Japan
Singapore
Taiwan
Indonesia
Korea
Malaysia
Philippines
Thailand
China
HK SAR
Dollars
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
CA
44
68
113
132
130
111
66
97
119
115
120
88
112
136
RC
-9
-8
0
27
26
57
35
1
-5
74
70
41
64
201
CA
3
5
6
4
11
15
14
15
19
15
13
16
19
28
RC
7
6
6
8
10
10
8
-6
4
2
3
-5
7
14
CA
11
12
9
7
7
5
11
7
3
8
9
18
26
29
RC
-1
10
0
1
9
-2
-2
-5
7
16
1
15
39
45
CA
-3
-4
-3
-2
-3
-6
-8
-5
4
6
8
7
8
8
RC
2
2
1
1
1
1
5
-2
6
4
2
-1
4
4
CA
-2
-8
-4
1
-4
-9
-23
-8
40
24
12
8
6
12
RC
-1
-1
3
3
5
7
1
-14
32
22
22
7
18
34
CA
-1
-4
-2
-3
-5
-9
-4
-6
10
13
8
7
7
11
RC
2
1
6
10
-2
-2
3
-6
5
5
-1
1
4
10
CA
-3
-1
-1
-3
-3
-2
-4
-4
2
7
6
1
4
2
RC
-1
2
1
0
1
0
4
-3
2
4
0
0
0
0
CA
-7
-8
-6
-6
-8
-14
-15
-3
14
12
9
6
8
8
RC
4
4
3
4
5
7
2
-12
3
5
-2
0
6
3
CA
12
13
6
-12
7
2
7
37
31
21
21
17
35
31
RC
12
14
-23
2
30
22
31
35
5
10
11
47
74
117
3
10
7
10
14
17
CA
RC
East Asia
4
6
8
6
6
8
29
-3
7
11
4
1
6
CA
56
74
116
125
136
93
45
133
241
230
217
182
248
255
RC
16
35
3
64
92
107
95
19
56
148
117
109
216
434
Figure 10: US and cumulative East Asian
Current Accounts (Billions of US
Dollars)
400
300
US
East Asia
200
billions of dollars
100
0
1980
-100
1982
1984
1986
-200
-300
-400
-500
-600
Data source: IMF: IFS.
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
I. The Dollar Standard and East Asia’s
Trade Surplus: The DFG Approach
Revived Bretton Woods: EA Exchange Rates are
deliberately undervalued to support an export
drive into American markets.
Exports are desired to promote “development”,
particularly in manufacturing.
Asian governments are willing to pay the cost of
investing in very low yield US Treasuries, and to
accept American FDI with high profit repatriation.
US gets finance for its fiscal deficits
Despite adjustment costs in US manufacturing,
the ongoing current-account deficit is sustainable
II. The Dollar Standard and East Asia’s
Trade Surplus: The MCS Approach
With the dollar as international money, the
efficiency of world trade and payments increases.
If the U.S. price level is stable, peripheral
countries will peg to the dollar to anchor their
own price levels—not to “undervalue” their
currencies, which would be inflationary.
Massive interventions by East Asian central banks
to prevent exchange appreciation incidentally
extend the US credit line with the rest of the
world, softening borrowing constraints on US
households and on the Federal Government.
The upshot has been falling US saving and large
current account deficits for more than 20 years.
Restraining American Deficits?
An attack on the dollar is unlikely because US
debts are denominated in its own currency, unlike
peripheral countries with “original sin”. The Fed
creates the definitive international money.
But heavy US foreign borrowing is transferred in
real terms through large American trade deficits,
mainly in manufactures.
The American concern with de-industrialization,
i.e., unduly rapid job losses in manufacturing,
should be linked to federal fiscal deficits and low
American personal saving.
Exchange rate changes, foreign trade restraints,
or tax breaks for manufacturers, won’t work.
Instead, with deliberate speed, move the federal
budget from deficit to surplus.
6
19 5
6
19 6
6
19 7
6
19 8
6
19 9
7
19 0
7
19 1
7
19 2
7
19 3
7
19 4
7
19 5
7
19 6
77
19
7
19 8
7
19 9
8
19 0
8
19 1
8
19 2
8
19 3
8
19 4
8
19 5
8
19 6
8
19 7
8
19 8
8
19 9
9
19 0
91
19
9
19 2
9
19 3
9
19 4
9
19 5
9
19 6
9
19 7
9
19 8
9
20 9
0
20 0
0
20 1
0
2 2
20 003
04
2Q
19
US Current Account and Manufacturing Sector
Trade Balance (% of GDP)
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
CA Balance
-4
Manufacturing Trade Balance
-5
-6
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis
Projection of Labor Growth in Manufacturing
under Balanced Manufacturing Trade
30.00
25.00
15.00
Share of Manufacturing
Employment
10.00
Projected Share of Manufacturing
Employment under Balanced
Manufacturing Trade
5.00
20
03
20
01
19
99
19
97
19
95
19
93
19
91
19
89
19
87
19
85
19
83
19
81
19
79
19
77
19
75
19
73
19
71
19
69
19
67
0.00
19
65
(%)
20.00
Conclusions for East Asia
Collectively pegging to the dollar enlarges the
zone of stable dollar prices far beyond trade with
the United States: stronger mutual anchoring of
national price levels
Anchors against the threat of appreciation and
deflation in creditor countries with “conflicted
virtue”—while stabilizing mutual cross rates of
exchange. Important for Japan and China.
Mutual exchange stability is a public good among
integrated economies.
An “Asian euro” is but a distant possibility, so
keying on the dollar is now the only feasible intra
Asian mechanism for securing exchange stability.