Import Tariffs and Quotas Under Perfect Competition

Download Report

Transcript Import Tariffs and Quotas Under Perfect Competition

IMPORT TARIFFS AND QUOTAS UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION

8 1

A Brief History of the World Trade Organization

2

The Gains from Trade

3

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

4

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

5

Import Quotas

6

Conclusions

Chapter Outline

• • • Introduction A Brief History of the World Trade Organization The Gains from Trade   Consumer and Producer Surplus Home Welfare    No-Trade Free Trade for a Small Country Gains from Trade  Home Import Demand Curve © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 2 of 136

Chapter Outline

• Import Tariffs for a Small Country   Free Trade for a Small Country Effect of the Tariff    Effect of the Tariff on Consumer Surplus Effect of the Tariff on Producer Surplus Effect of the Tariff on Government Revenue    Overall Effect of the Tariff on Welfare Production Loss Consumption Loss  Why are Tariffs Used?

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 3 of 136

Chapter Outline

• • Import Tariffs for a Large Country   Foreign Export Supply Effect of the Tariff    Terms of Trade Home Welfare Foreign and World Welfare Import Quotas  Import Quota in a Small Country    Free Trade Equilibrium Effect of the Quota Effect on Welfare • Allocation of Quota © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 4 of 136

Chapter Outline

•      Costs of Import Quotas in the U.S.

Growth in Exports from China Welfare Cost of MFA Import Quality Reaction of the United States and Europe Conclusions © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 5 of 136

Learning Objectives

• • • • • Understand what a

trade policy

is and why it is used.

Understand the history of the World Trade Organization (WTO) and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Understand what a tariff is and why it is used.

Understand and be able to explain the effect of a tariff on a small country.

Understand and be able to explain the effect of a tariff on a large country.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 6 of 136

Learning Objectives

• • • • Understand how a large country could potentially gain from implementing a tariff.

Understand what a quota is and why it is used.

Understand and be able to explain the effects of a quota on a country.

Understand how the quota can have costs even greater than tariffs.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 7 of 136

Introduction

• • • During the 2000 presidential campaign, President George W. Bush promised to consider implementing a tariff on the imports of steel.

This was a political move to secure votes in large steel-producing states as the tariffs would “protect” the domestic producers of steel.

The steel tariff is an example of a trade policy —a government action meant to influence the amount of international trade.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 8 of 136

Introduction

• • • • Because gains from trade are unevenly spread, producers often feel the government should help them limit losses due to competition from trade.

Trade policy can include the use of import tariffs (taxes on imports), import quotas (limits on imports), and subsidies for exports.

This chapter will focus on the use of tariffs and quotas as trade policy.

The international governing body, the World Trade Organization (WTO), acts as a forum for trade issues between countries.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 9 of 136

Introduction

• • • We will look at the history of the WTO, beginning with its precursor, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). We will then examine in detail the most commonly used trade policy, the tariff, looking at why they are used and the consequences of their use.

The chapter will also examine the use of import quotas, showing that although their costs are similar to tariffs, they can also be greater.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 10 of 136

Introduction

• • • • Given the potentially greater costs of quotas, they have been greatly reduced under the WTO.

We will assume that firms are perfectly competitive. They produce a homogeneous good and are small compared to the market.

Under perfect competition, each firm is a price taker in its market.

Imperfect competition will be evaluated in the next chapter.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 11 of 136

A Brief History of the World Trade Organization

• • • When peace was reestablished following WWII, representatives of 44 countries met in Bretton Woods, NH, to discuss the rebuilding of Europe and issues with high trade barriers and unstable exchange rates.

The outcome was an agreement outlining an international system of free trade, convertible currencies, and fixed exchange rates.

As part of this Breton Woods Agreement, the GATT was established in 1947 to reduce barriers to trade between nations.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 12 of 136

A Brief History of the World Trade Organization

• • • • Under the GATT, countries met periodically to negotiate for lower trade barriers between them.

Each meeting was named for the location where it took place and at the Uruguay Round, the WTO was established.

The WTO greatly expanded GATT by adding rules that govern an expanded set of global interactions through binding agreements.

The most recent round of the WTO was the Doha Round, in Doha, Qatar, which began in November 2001.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 13 of 136

A Brief History of the World Trade Organization

• Some Articles of GATT which still govern trade in the WTO: 1.

2.

3.

A nation must extend the same tariffs to all trading partners that are WTO members. This is the “most favored nation” clause Tariffs may be imposed in response to unfair trade practices such as

dumping

Countries should not limit the quantity of goods and services that they import. Article XI states that countries should not maintain quotas against imports 4.

Countries should declare

export subsidies

provided to particular firms, sectors, or industries © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 14 of 136

A Brief History of the World Trade Organization

5.

 Countries can temporarily raise tariffs for certain products. Article XIX is called the

safeguard provision

or the

escape clause

and is our focus in this chapter.

The importing country can temporarily raise a tariff when domestic producers are suffering due to import competition.

 European governments strenuously objected to the U.S. steel tariffs, and filed a complaint against the U.S. with the WTO.

 A panel at the WTO ruled in favor of the European countries, entitling them to retaliate by placing tariffs of their own on $2.2 billion worth of U.S. exports.

 This lead President Bush to remove the steel tariffs in December 2003.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 15 of 136

A Brief History of the World Trade Organization

6.

  Regional trade agreements are permitted under Articles XXIV of the GATT Free trade areas Customs unions © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 16 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• • We will now demonstrate the gains from trade using Home demand and supply curves, together with the concepts of

consumer surplus

and

producer surplus.

Consumer and Producer Surplus    Figure 8.1 (a) shows the Home demand curve D where consumers face a price of P 1 .

A person buying unit D 2 has to pay of P 1 .

is willing to pay P 2 , but only The individual obtains a surplus of (P 2 – P 1 ) from being able to purchase the good for less than their willingness to pay.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 17 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• Consumer and Producer Surplus  For each unit before D 1 , the consumer’s value exceeds the purchase price of P 1 .

 Adding up the surplus obtained on each unit purchased, from zero to D 1 , gives the total surplus.

 The total satisfaction that consumers receive from the purchased quantity D 1 , over and above the amount P 1 D 1 they have paid.

that  Consumer surplus then is the shaded region between the demand curve and the market price, up to the total quantity purchased, D 1 in this case.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 18 of 136

The Gains from Trade

Figure 8.1 (a)

Price Total Consumer surplus, CS Adding up all the individual surplus for each point on the demand curve gives us total 1 will buy a total of D 1 .

to pay P 1 equal to (P 2 -P 1 ) sold P 2 P 1 Surplus for consumer purchasing quantity D 2 D 2 D 1 D Quantity © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 19 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• • • • Part (b) of figure 8.1 illustrates producer surplus.

At the price of P 1 , the industry will supply S 1.

Remember that the supply curve represents a firm’s marginal cost of production.

The firm supplying unit S 0 could produce it with a marginal cost of P 0 , but is able to sell it for P 1 .

 This gives the firm a surplus of (P 1 – P 0 ). © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 20 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• • • • For each unit sold before S 1 , the marginal cost to the firm is less than the sale price of P 1 .

If we add up all these individual surpluses obtained for each unit sold from zero to S 1 , we get the total producer surplus (PS). Producer surplus is the area above the supply curve to the price received, up to the quantity sold.

We can also refer to PS as the return to fixed factors of production in the industry, and can loosely refer to it as “profit.” © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 21 of 136

The Gains from Trade

Figure 8.1 (b)

Price Total Producer surplus, PS S The supply curve gives us the MC of P 0 , but gets P supply curve gives us total producer surplus 1 1 0 . That , producers 1 —the area 0 between the supply and the price received —up to the quantity sold.

P 1 P 0 Surplus for firm producing quantity S 0 S 0 S 1 Quantity © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 22 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• Home Welfare  Again we consider the world of two countries, Home and Foreign, with producers and consumers.

 Total Home welfare can be measured by adding up consumer and producer surplus.

 The greater the total surplus, the greater the total home welfare —the better off the country is.

 We will compare the welfare in Home in no-trade and free-trade situations.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 23 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• No-Trade   In figure 8.2 (a), the no trade equilibrium occurs at the autarky price of P A , where quantity demanded equals quantity supplied at Q 0 .

Consumer and producer surplus are shown as the areas defined before. Adding these gives total surplus for Home before trade.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 24 of 136

Figure 8.2

The Gains from Trade

(a) No-Trade

Price No-trade equilibrium S CS A P A PS D Q 0 Quantity © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 25 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• Free Trade for a Small Country   Suppose Home can now engage in trade. The world price P W is determined by the supply and demand in the world market (shown in in figure 8.2 (b)).

 Suppose Home is a small country.

  Price taker in the world market Faces a fixed price at P W   Assume P W is below the Home no-trade price P A .

 At the lower price, Home quantity demanded will increase to D 1 decrease to S 1 .

and Home quantity supplied will Home will be an importer of the product at the world price.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 26 of 136

The Gains from Trade

Figure 8.2 (b) Free Trade

Price At the free trade price of P W , Home supply will fall to S 1 and Home demand will rise to D 1 .

S P A P W D Imports will make up for the excess demand and will equal (D 1 – S 1 ) S 1 D 1 Quantity

Imports

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 27 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• • Consumers gain more than the producers lose indicating total Home welfare increased.

By looking at the changes in surplus we see: • • Rise in consumer surplus Fall in producer surplus

Net effect on Home welfare

+

(b+d)

-

b

d

d

is a measure of the gains from trade for the importing country due to free trade.

We can measure this gain directly using the formula for the area of the triangle = ½ bh  Welfare increase = ½ (M 1 )(P A -P W ) © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 28 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• Gains from Trade  We can now measure the welfare effects for producers and consumers under free trade.

 Since price has fallen under trade, we would expect this to be good for consumers and therefore consumer surplus to increase.

 Consumer surplus increases by

b+d

in figure 8.2 (b).

 Similarly, a lower price is worse for producers so we would expect producer surplus to fall.

 Producer surplus falls by

b

in figure 8.2 (b).

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 29 of 136

The Gains from Trade

Figure 8.2

Price

(b) Free Trade

At lower world price, consumer surplus increases to

a+b+d

 an increase of

b+d

from no-trade P A P W

c a b d

S At lower world price, producer surplus falls to

c

 a decrease of

b

from no-trade Gain in trade is triangle

d

with area equal to ½(M 1 )(P A -P W ) D S 1 D 1 Quantity

Imports, M1

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 30 of 136

The Gains from Trade

• Home Import Demand Curve  We can derive the

import demand curve

, shown in figure 8.3

 The relationship between the world price of a good and the quantity of imports demanded by Home consumers.

 At the no-trade equilibrium, there are zero imports  This is shown as point A′ in panel (b).   At the world price of P W , the quantity demanded is greater than quantity supplied, and we import M 1 .

 This is point B in panel (b). Joining A′ and B gives import demand curve M.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 31 of 136

The Gains from Trade

Figure 8.3

Price No-trade equilibrium (a) S Price (b) Each point on the import demand curve is a point that corresponds to Home imports at a given Home price A' P A A B P W S 1 Q 0 D 1 D Quantity M 1 Imports, M 1 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor Import demand curve, M Imports 32 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• • • We can now use the supply/demand framework to show what happens when a small country imposes a tariff.

Remember that a small country is one where its tariff does not have any effect on the world price.

This means the price charged to Home consumers will increase by the amount of the tariff.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 33 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Free Trade for a Small Country  We start with the free-trade-equilibrium for the Home country (in figure 8.4).

 The Foreign export supply curve X* is horizontal at the world price P W .

 This means that Home can import an amount at the price P W without having an impact on that price.

 In free-trade-equilibrium, home demand is D 1 , Home supply is S 1 , and imports are M 1 .

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 34 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Effect of the Tariff  With an import tariff of t dollars, the export supply curve facing Home shifts up by exactly the amount of the tariff.

  The new export supply curve shifts up to X*+t.

 The new intersection now occurs at the price of P W +t and the import quantity of M 2 .

The import tariff has reduced the amount imported, from M 1 under free trade to M the higher price.

2 under the tariff, due to © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 35 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Effect of the Tariff   At the higher import price, the quantity demanded at Home falls and the quantity supplied at Home rises from S 1 to S 2 . .

However, as firms increase the quantity produced, the marginal costs of production rise.

  The home supply curve reflects marginal costs so the Home price rises along S until firms are supplying quantity S 2 at a MC just equal to the new price, P W +t.

The domestic price will equal the import price.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 36 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Effect of the Tariff  Home price rises to P W +t thereby decreasing the quantity demanded at Home    Higher prices increase the quantity supplied at Home.

Less excess demand therefore imports fall.

Foreign exporters still receive the “net-of-tariff” price, P W .

 These changes affect producer and consumer surplus, and overall Home welfare.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 37 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

Figure 8.4

Price No-trade equilibrium Price Home price rises by the amount of the tariff.

Home supply increases and Home demand decreases  Imports fall to M 2 S A C P W +t P W B S 1 D 2 S 2 M 2 D 1 D Quantity M 2 M 1 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor M X*+t Foreign export supply, X* Imports 38 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Effect of the Tariff on Consumer Surplus  With the tariff, consumers now pay the higher price, P W +t, and their surplus is the area under the demand curve and above the higher price, P W +t.

 The fall in consumer surplus due to the tariff is the area in-between the two prices and to the left of Home demand,

(a+b+c+d)

in panel (a.1) of figure 8.5.

 This area is the amount that consumers lose due to the higher price caused by the tariff.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 39 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

Figure 8.5 (a.1)

No-trade equilibrium Price S Lost consumer surplus due to the higher price with the tariff is equal to the shaded area

(a+b+c+d)

A P W +t P W a b c d S 1 S 2 D 2 D 1 D Quantity M 2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 40 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Effect of the Tariff on Producer Surplus  With the tariff, producer surplus is the area above the supply and below the higher price, P W +t.

 Since the tariff increases Home price, firms can sell more goods, and producer surplus increases  This area,

a

in figure 8.5 (a.2), is the amount that Home firms gain due to the higher price caused by the tariff.

 Increases in producer surplus can benefit Home workers but at the expense of consumers.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 41 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

Figure 8.5 (a.2)

No-trade equilibrium Price S The gain in producer surplus due to the higher price with the tariff is equal to the shaded area

(a)

A P W +t P W a b c d S 1 S 2 D 2 D 1 D Quantity M 2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 42 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Effect of the Tariff on Government Revenue  In addition to the tariff’s impact on consumers and producers, it also affects government revenue.

 The amount of revenue collected is the tariff t times the quantity of imports (D 2 – S 2 ).  In figure 8.5 panel (a.3), the revenue is shown by area

c.

 The collection of revenue is a gain for the government in the importing country.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 43 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

Figure 8.5 (a.3)

Price P W +t a No-trade equilibrium b A S d The gain in government revenue due to the tariff is equal to the shaded area

(c)

This equals the tariff, t, times the quantity of imports, M 2 c P W D S 1 S 2 D 2 D 1 Quantity M 2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 44 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Overall Effect of the Tariff on Welfare  We can now summarize the total impact of the tariff on the welfare of the Home importing country by adding the gains and losses for each party.

 Note, we do not care whether the consumers facing higher prices are rich or poor, and do not care whether the specific factors in the industry earn a lot or a little.

 Under this approach, transferring one dollar from consumer to producer surplus will have no impact on overall welfare.

 We are simply evaluating the

efficiency

of the tariff.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 45 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Overall Effect of the Tariff on Welfare  The overall impact of the tariff in the small country can be summarized as follows: Fall in consumer surplus Rise in producer surplus Rise in government revenue

Net effect on Home welfare

-(a+b+c+d) +a +c

-(b+d)

• The areas b and d in figure 8.5 (a) correspond to the triangle (b+d) in figure 8.5 (b) and is the net welfare loss.

 We refer to this area as a

deadweight loss

—it is not offset by a gain elsewhere in the economy.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 46 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

Figure 8.5 (a)

Price P W +t P W a No-trade equilibrium b c A S d The deadweight loss is the loss to Home that is not offset by a corresponding gain

a

is a transfer from consumers to producers

c

is a transfer from consumers to government

(b+d)

is deadweight loss — losses not offset by other gains D S 1 S 2 D 2 D 1 Quantity M 2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 47 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

Figure 8.5 (b)

Price Dead weight loss due to tariff,

b+d

C X*+ t X* M 2 M 1 M Imports © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 48 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Overall Effect of the Tariff on Welfare  The area

a

is effectively a transfer from consumers to producers via the higher domestic prices induced by the tariff.

 The area

c

, the gain in government revenue, is a transfer from consumers to the government.

 The deadweight loss,

(b+d),

is measured by the two triangles

b

and

d.

 The two triangles can each be given a precise interpretation.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 49 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Production Loss  The base of b is the net increase in Home supply due to the tariff, from S1 to S2.

 The height of this triangle is the increase in marginal costs due to the increase in supply.

  The fact that marginal costs are greater than world price means that this country is producing the extra supply inefficiently.

 Fewer resources would be used if imported rather than produced at home.

The area of b is the production loss or

efficiency loss

— due to producing at marginal costs above world price.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 50 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Small Country

• Consumption Loss   The triangle

d

also has a precise definition.

Due to the tariff, the price increase from, P W to P W +t reduces quantity consumed at Home from D 1 to D 2 .

 The area of the triangle can be interpreted as the drop in consumer surplus for those individuals who are no longer able to consume the units from D 1 of the higher price.

to D 2 because  We refer to this drop in consumer surplus as the

consumption loss

for the economy.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 51 of 136

Why are Tariffs Used?

• • Finding that tariffs always lead to deadweight losses for small countries explains why most economists are opposed to them.

Why then do so many countries use tariffs?

 One idea is that developing countries do not have any other source of revenue.

 Import tariffs are “easy-to-collect” because every country has customs agents at major ports checking the goods crossing the borders.

 However, to the extent that developing countries recognize that tariffs have a higher deadweight loss, we would expect that over time they will shift away from such “easy-to-collect” taxes.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 52 of 136

Why are Tariffs Used?

• Why then do so many countries use tariffs?

  A second reason is politics.

If the government cares more about producer surplus than consumer surplus, it might decide to use the tariff despite the deadweight loss it incurs.

 The benefits to producers (and their workers) are typically more concentrated on specific firms and states than the costs to consumers, which are spread nationwide.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 53 of 136

Globalization and Developing Countries

• • • SIDE BAR Developing countries rely on “easy-to-collect” tariffs over “hard-to-collect” income and value added taxes.

As globalization expands, we would expect these countries to move away from tariffs to the more hard-to-collect revenues.

According to one research study, the ratio of tax revenue to GDP obtained from easy-to-collect taxes fell by about 20% in developing countries between the 1980s and 1990s.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 54 of 136

Globalization and Developing Countries

• • • SIDE BAR At the same time the ratio of tax revenue to GDP from “hard-to-collect” revenue rose by 9% in the developing countries.

The loss from “easy-to-collect” taxes was not enough to make up for the gain from “hard-to-collect” taxes.

 It is harder to improve the performance of “hard-to-collect” taxes than it is to shift away from the “easy-to-collect” taxes for low income countries.

High- and middle-income countries were able to obtain a net increase in tax revenue from this process.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 55 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

• • • APPLICATION We can use our small country model from above to calculate a rough estimate of how costly these tariffs were in terms of welfare.

We will estimate the deadweight loss due to the U.S. steel tariff in place from March 2002 to December 2003.

President Bush requested that the U.S. International Trade Commission (ITC) initiate a Section 201 investigation into the steel industry.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 56 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

• • • APPLICATION The ITC determined that the conditions were met and recommended that tariffs be put in place to protect the U.S. steel industry.

The tariffs varied across products, ranging from 10 to 20% —shown in Table 8.1—then falling over time to be eliminated after 3 years.

The ITC decision showed it thought that the losses from rising imports and falling prices met the conditions of “serious injury.” 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 57 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

• • APPLICATION President Bush took the recommendation of the ITC but applied even higher tariffs, ranging from 8% to 30%.

Knowing the U.S. trading partners would be upset by this, President Bush exempted some countries from the tariffs.

 These included Canada, Mexico, Jordan, and Israel, which all have free trade agreements with the U.S., and 100 small developing countries that were exporting only a very small amount of steel to the U.S.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 58 of 136

APPLICATION

Table 8.1

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 59 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

• APPLICATION Deadweight Loss due to the Steel Tariff      We need to estimate the areas of triangle

b+d

in figure 8.5(b).

we found The base is the change in imports, ΔM, and the height is the increase in domestic price, ΔP = t.

Deadweight loss then equals DWL = ½ t ΔM.

It is convenient to measure the deadweight loss relative to the value of imports, which is P W *M.

We will also use the percentage tariff, t/P W , and the percentage change in the quantity of imports, % ΔM = ΔM/M.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 60 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

APPLICATION Price

Figure 8.5 (b)

Deadweight loss due to the tariff,

b+d

We can measure DWL with the area of the triangle b+d from figure 8.5 (b) DWL = ½ t ΔM t P W +t P W

c

M M 2 ΔM M 1 Imports 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 61 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

• APPLICATION Using these definitions, the deadweight loss relative to the value of imports can be rewritten as:

DWL P W M

 1 2

t

M P W M

 1 2

P t W

% 

M

• The most commonly used products had a tariff of 30%, so the percentage increase in the price is t/P W = 0.3, leading to % ΔM = 0.3.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 62 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

APPLICATION • This leads to a DWL of

DWL P W M

 1 2

t P W

  % 

M

 1 2 ( 0 .

3 )( 0 .

3 )  4 .

5 % • The value of steel imports affected by the tariff was about $4.7 billion prior to March 2002 and $3.5 billion after March 2002.

 Average imports over the two years were then $4.1 billion.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 63 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

• • APPLICATION Applying the DWL of 4.5% to the average import value of $4.1 billion, then the dollar magnitude of deadweight loss is equal to $185 million.

This deadweight loss reflects the net annual loss to the U.S. from applying the tariff.

 A steel worker might think this is ok to protect jobs, but consumers would not agree.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 64 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

• APPLICATION Response of the European Countries     The tariffs on steel most heavily affected Europe, Japan, and South Korea, along with some developing countries.

The countries in the European Union therefore took action by bringing the case to the WTO.

The WTO has a formal

dispute settlement procedure

, under which countries can bring complaint and have it evaluated.

The WTO ruled that the U.S. had failed to prove its steel industry had been harmed by imports and therefore did not have the right to impose the tariffs.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 65 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

• APPLICATION Response of the European Countries    Even if we accept that there might be an argument on equity or fairness grounds for temporarily protecting an industry facing import competition, it is hard to argue that such protection should occur due to a change in exchange rates.

The appreciation of the dollar lowered prices for all other imports too, so many industries faced competition.

Why should the steel industry be protected and not the others?

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 66 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel

• APPLICATION Response of the European Countries     The WTO ruling entitled the European Union and other countries to retaliate against the U.S. by imposing tariffs of their own against U.S. exports.

The EU quickly began to draw up a list of products and naturally picked products that would have the greatest impact on the U.S.

The threat of tariffs led President Bush to reconsider the U.S. tariffs on steel, and on December 5, 2003, he announced that they would be suspended.

You can see how this chain of events could lead to a

tariff war.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 67 of 136

Europe’s Little List

HEADLINES • How are steel and orange juice related?

• When the WTO ruled that the U.S. tariffs on steel violated international trade law, it allowed the European Union to implement $2.2 billion in retaliatory taxes on U.S. exports.

• On the list were oranges and orange juice, big exports of Florida, a major swing state with Jeb Bush as Governor —the President’s brother.

• Michigan and Wisconsin apples and California farm products were also on the list.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 68 of 136

Europe’s Little List

HEADLINES • • Another industrial group targeted was the makers of industrial farm equipment like John Deere and Caterpillar —both based in the key electoral state of Illinois.

Toilet paper might seem like an odd item for the hit list, but is part of the paper industry, which was targeted because it affected a number of important states.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 69 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• • Under the small country assumption that we have used so far, the importing country is always harmed due to the tariff.

 The small country is a world price taker.

If we consider a large enough importing country or a large country, however, then we might expect that its tariff will change the world price.

 Its imports are large enough that it can affect world price with a change in its imports.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 70 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Foreign Export Supply  If the Home country is large, then the Foreign export supply curve X* is no longer horizontal at the world price P W .

 We need to derive the foreign export supply curve using the Foreign market demand and supply curves.

 In panel (a) of figure 8.6, we show the Foreign demand curve D* and supply curve S*, giving price of P A * at A*.  At this point, Foreign exports are zero.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 71 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Foreign Export Supply   Suppose the world price is P W above P A *. At the higher price, Foreign quantity demanded is lower at D 1 *, but quantity supplied by foreign firms is higher at S 1 *.  Foreign excess supply of X 1 * = S 1 * - D 1 *, will be exported at the price of P W at point B*.  Connecting A* and B* gives the upward sloping Foreign export supply curve, X*.  Combining with Home import demand, M, we get an equilibrium at P W and X 1 *. * © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 72 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

Figure 8.6

(a) Foreign Mkt

Pric e World price increases to P W , increasing exports to X 1 * D* At the world price, P A *, exports are zero at A*’ S* Price

(b) World Mkt

This gives us our Foreign export supply curve for the large country Foreign export supply, X* B* P W Home import demand, M P A * A*' A* Exports D 1 * S 1 * Quantity X 1 * Foreign exports, X 1 * © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 73 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Effect of the Tariff  Figure 8.7 we show the effect when Home applies a tariff of t dollars on imports.

 The tariff increases the cost to Foreign producers of supplying to the Home market.

 Foreign export supply curve shifts up by exactly the amount of the tariff, shifting from X* to X*+t.

 The new supply crosses demand at C, giving a new Home price.

 However, notice that the price that Foreign producers receive, P*, ends up below the original free trade price.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 74 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Effect of the Tariff  The price Home pays for its imports P*+t rises by less than the amount of the tariff, t, as compared to the initial world price, P W .

 This is because the price received by foreign exporters, P*, has fallen as compared to the initial world price, P W .

 Foreign producers are essentially “absorbing” a part of the tariff, by lowering their price from P W to P*.  The tariff drives a wedge between what Home consumers pay and what foreign producers receive, with the difference, t, going to the Home government.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 75 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

Figure 8.7

(without welfare effects)

(a) Home market

Price No-trade equilibrium S A

t

P*+t P W P* D Price

t (b) Foreign market

C C* B*

t

X*+t X* M Imports S 1 S 2 M 2 D 2 D 1 Quantity M 2 M 1 M 1 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 76 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Terms of Trade  Remember terms of trade is the ratio of export prices to import prices.

 In order to measure terms of trade, we want to use the net-of-tariff import price, P*.  Since P* is lower than P W , it follows that the Home terms of trade has increased.

 We might expect, therefore, that the Home country gains from the tariff  We need to analyze the impact of the tariff on Home consumers, producers, and government revenue.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 77 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Home Welfare  The higher Home price makes consumers worse off, lowering consumer surplus (shown by

(a+b+c+d)

in figure 8.7).

 Home firms are better off with the higher price and increased surplus,

a

.

 Revenue collected from the tariff equals the amount of the tariff, t, times the new amount of imports, M 2 , giving total revenue of

(c+e).

 Summing all the gains and losses, we obtain the overall impact of the tariff in the large country.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 78 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Home Welfare Fall in consumer surplus Rise in producer surplus Rise in government revenue Net effect on Home welfaree -(a+b+c+d) +a +(c + e) – (b+d) + (e) • • • • The triangle (b+d) is the deadweight loss due to the tariff.

But notice, there is a source of gain, e, that offsets part of the loss.

If

e > (b+d),

then Home is better off. If

e < (b+d),

then Home is worse off.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 79 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

Figure 8.7

(with welfare effects)

If the gain of e is greater than the loss of (b+d), Home gains Price

(a) Home market

No-trade equilibrium Price

(b) Foreign market

S A P*+t P W P*

a b c d e

D

e

C C*

b+d

B* t X*+t X* M S 1 S 2 D 2 D 1 Quantity M 2 M 1 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor Imports 80 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Home Welfare  We see that a large importer might gain due to the application of a tariff.

 However, for the large country, any net gain due to the tariff comes at the expense of the Foreign exporters.

 Although Home might gain from the tariff, Foreign definitely loses © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 81 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Foreign and World Welfare  The Foreign loss, measured by

(e+f

) also in figure 8.7, is the loss in Foreign producer surplus from selling fewer goods to Home at a lower price.

 The area

e

equivalent is the terms-of-trade gain terms-of-trade loss for Home but an for Foreign.

 Additionally, there is an extra deadweight loss in Foreign of f, giving a combined total greater than the benefits to Home.

 Therefore, it is sometimes called the “beggar thy neighbor” tariff.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 82 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

Figure 8.7

(with welfare effects)

Foreign loses

(e+f)

as loss of Foreign producer surplus, from selling fewer goods at a lower price

(a) Home market (b) Foreign market

Price No-trade equilibrium Price S A P*+t P W P*

a b c d e

D

e

C C*

f b+d

B* t X*+t X* M S 1 S 2 D 2 D 1 Quantity M 2 M 1 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor Imports 83 of 136

Import Tariffs for a Large Country

• Foreign and World Welfare  Adding together the change in Home and Foreign welfare,

e

cancels out leaving a net loss to world welfare of

(b+d+f).

 We saw this triangle in panel (b) of figure 8.7, which is the deadweight loss for the world.

 The fact that the large country tariff leads to a world deadweight loss is another reason that most economists oppose the use of tariffs.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 84 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

• • APPLICATION Returning to the U.S. tariff on steel, we can reevaluate the effect on U.S. welfare in the large country case.

If the U.S. is a large enough importer of steel, then the foreign export price will fall and the U.S. import price will rise by less than the tariff.

 It is possible that the U.S. gained from the tariff.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 85 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

• APPLICATION Optimal Tariff      We can compute the deadweight loss (area

b

+

d

) and the terms-of-trade gain (area

e

) for each imported steel product.

This would give us the information to see if the U.S. gained from the steel tariffs.

Rather than do all these calculations, however, we can use the concept of the

optimal tariff.

This is the tariff that leads to the maximum increase in welfare for the importing country.

We have shown that for a small tariff, a large country can gain. But if the tariff is too large, the country will still lose.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 86 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

• APPLICATION Optimal Tariff      Figure 8.8 graphs Home welfare against the level of the tariff.

Free trade is at point B where the tariff is zero.

Starting at B, increasing the tariff can increase the importer’s welfare, to a point.

If the tariff is too large, then welfare will fall below the free trade level of welfare.

 For example, a prohibitive tariff is one so high there are no imports —this is point A.

Given this, you can see that the highest point of welfare for the importing country is shown by C.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 87 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

APPLICATION

Figure 8.8

Importer’s Welfare Terms of trade gain exceeds deadweight loss C The Optimal tariff maximizes the Importer’s welfare, Point C Too high of a tariff will decrease importer’s welfare and can increase to the point where there is no trade Terms of trade gain is less than deadweight loss B' Free Trade B No Trade A Optimal Tariff Prohibitive Tariff 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor Tariff 88 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

• APPLICATION Optimal Tariff Formula  The optimal tariff depends on the elasticity of Foreign export supply, E X *.  This is the percentage change in the quantity exported in response to a percent change in the world price of the export.

  If the export supply curve is very steep, there is little response in quantity supplied —inelastic—E X * is low.

If the export supply curve is very flat, there is a large response in quantity supplied —elastic—E X * is high.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 89 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

• APPLICATION Optimal Tariff Formula  Optimal Tariff = 1/E X *. For a small importing country, the elasticity of Foreign export supply is infinite, and so the optimal tariff is zero.

 As the elasticity of Foreign export supply decreases, Foreign export supply curve is steeper, the optimal tariff is higher.

 With a steep Foreign export supply curve, Foreign exporters will lower their price more in response to the tariff.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 90 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

• APPLICATION Optimal Tariffs for Steel  If we apply this formula to the U.S. steel tariffs, we can see how the tariffs applied compare to the theoretical optimal tariff.

 Table 8.2 shows various steel products along with their respective elasticities of export supply to the U.S.

 We can compare the actual tariff to the optimal tariff to see where there were gains and where there were losses from the tariffs.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 91 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

• • APPLICATION For alloy steel flat-rolled products, the actual tariff was 30%, which is far below the optimal tariff.

  The terms of trade gain for that product was higher than the deadweight loss.

U.S. welfare is above its free trade level.

In summary, two products had terms of trade greater than the deadweight loss, but the third had a larger deadweight loss.

 The first two illustrate the large country case, while the third illustrates the small country case.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 92 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

APPLICATION

Table 8.2

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 93 of 136

U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again

• • APPLICATION Even if there was an overall terms of trade gain for the U.S. when adding up across all steel products, that gain would be at the expense of the European countries and other steel exporters.

By allowing exporting countries to retaliate with tariffs, the WTO prevents importers from using optimal tariffs to their own advantage.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 94 of 136

Import Quotas

• On January 1, 2005, China was poised to become the world’s largest exporter of textiles and apparel.

 On that date, the Multifibre Arrangement (MFA) was abolished.

 Under the MFA, import quotas restricted the amount of nearly every textile and apparel product that was imported to Canada, Europe, and the U.S.

 The quotas were to protect their own domestic firms producing those products.

 With the end of the MFA, China was ready to enjoy greatly increased imports.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 95 of 136

Import Quotas

• • • The threat of import competition from China led the U.S. and Europe to negotiate new quotas with China.

There are other examples of quotas  Europe had a quota on the imports of bananas that allowed for a greater number of bananas to enter from its former colonies in Africa than from Latin America.  In 2005, this quota became a tariff.

In the next section, we explain how quotas affect the importing and exporting countries, and examine the differences between quotas and tariffs.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 96 of 136

Europe Reaches Deal on Banana Imports

HEADLINES • • The European Union changed their trade barriers to allow banana imports from countries that were once European colonies and to restrict imports from other countries, primarily in Latin America.

The proposal was to implement one import tariff but no quotas on bananas except for former French, British, and Portuguese colonies, which will continue to enjoy duty-free access.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 97 of 136

Europe Reaches Deal on Banana Imports

HEADLINES • • This change replaces the prior trade policy that was a mixture of tariffs and quotas, but is still higher than the Latin American countries are content with.

The European countries are split over what to do about these policies.  Some want to protect their own growers’ interests and others want to keep prices low for consumers.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 98 of 136

Sweet Opportunity

HEADLINES • • • The current U.S. sugar program guarantees that American sugar producers receive a set price for their product.

If they are not able to sell all their sugar at the “break-even” price after accounting for their loans, they can sell the excess to the U.S. Department of Agriculture.

To keep from storing a large stock of sugar, the U.S. regulates supply by imposing import quotas on sugar.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 99 of 136

Sweet Opportunity

HEADLINES • • • But, the U.S. price of sugar has been two to three times higher than the world price of sugar for about 25 years.

The longer the protection holds, the more inefficient the U.S. producers become, and the more powerful they become as a special interest group.

Given that the current world price of sugar has increased and put foreign producers on par with the U.S., there is an opportunity to do away with the sugar program.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 100 of 136

Import Quotas

• • Import Quota in a Small Country Free Trade Equilibrium  Figure 8.9 (a) shows the free-trade-equilibrium at a world price of P W , home quantity demanded of D 1 , quantity supplied of S 1 , with imports of M 1 as before.

 Assuming the country is small means the world price is not affected by the import quota so the Foreign export supply curve, X*, is horizontal at P W.

 We can see the free trade amount of imports in panel (b) as well: M 1 at P W .

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 101 of 136

Import Quotas

Figure 8.9

(without quota) At P W , Home Supplies S 1 , Demands D 1 , and Imports M 1 No-trade equilibrium S Price Price A In free trade equilibrium for a small country, Foreign faces a horizontal export supply curve, X*, at the world price P W P W S 1 D 1 M 1

(a) Home market

D Quantity M 1 B

(b) Import market

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor Foreign export supply, X* Home import demand, M Imports 102 of 136

Import Quotas

• Effect of the Quota  Suppose the import quota of M 2

Quantity imported cannot exceed this amount.

 The essentially gives us a vertical supply curve, X in panel b (at prices above P W ).

 Fixes the import quantity at M 2 .

 The vertical export supply curve now intersects import demand at point C, which establishes the Home price of P 2 .

 In panel a, the price of P 2 quantity supplied to S 2 leads firms to increase the and consumers to decrease their quantity demanded to D 2 .

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 103 of 136

Import Quotas

• Effect of the Tariff  The import quota leads to an increase in the Home price and a reduction in Home imports, just like the tariff.

  We can see what the equivalent tariff, the tariff that would be set to give the same quantity and price as the quota, would be: t = P 2 – P W .

For every level of import quota, there is an equivalent import tariff.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 104 of 136

Import Quotas

• Effect on Welfare  The rise in price from the quota leads to a fall in consumer surplus:

(a+b+c+d).

 The increase in price facing Home producers leads to a gain in producer surplus:

a.

 What changes with the quota is the area

c

which was government revenue under the tariff.

 With a quota, whoever is actually importing the good will be able to earn

c

, the difference between the world price and the higher Home price times the imports sold in the Home market.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 105 of 136

Figure 8.9

(with quota) No-trade equilibrium

Import Quotas

Consumers loses surplus of (a+b+c+d), producers gain (a).

loss of (b+d) like the tariff Welfare of Home depends on what happens to (c). 2 2 S Price P 2 P W

a b

S 1 S A 2

c

D 2

d

D 1 D Quantity Price

c

r F o i e g n r e x p o C t s M 2 u

b+d

M 1 B (a) Home market © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ p International Economics l ▪ y Feenstra/Taylor Foreign export supply, X* Home import demand, M Imports 106 of 136

Import Quotas

• • The difference between these two prices is the rent associated with the quota.

Area

c

represents the total quota

rents.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 107 of 136

Import Quotas

• 1.

There are four possible ways these rents can be allocated.

 Giving the Quota to Home Firms: 

Quota licenses

can be given to Home firms Permits to import the quantity allowed under the quota system.

 The net effects on Home welfare due to the quota are then as follows: Fall in consumer surplus Rise in producer surplus Quota rents earned at Home

Net effect on Home welfare:

-(a+b+c+d) +a +c

-(b+d)

  This is the same loss we saw with a tariff.

(b+d) is still a deadweight loss associated with the quota.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 108 of 136

Import Quotas

2.

 Rent Seeking Because of the gains associated with owning a quota license, firms have an incentive to engage in inefficient activities in order to obtain them.

 How licenses are allocated matters.

a.

If licenses are allocated in proportion to each firm’s production, Home firms will likely produce more than they can sell

just to obtain the import licenses for the following year .

b.

Firms might engage in bribery or other lobbying activities obtain the licenses.

to © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 109 of 136

Import Quotas

 Some suggest that the waste of resources devoted to rent seeking could be as large as the value of the rents themselves,

c.

 If rent seeking occurs, welfare loss of quota is: Fall in consumer surplus

-(a+b+c+d)

Rise in producer surplus

+a

Net effect on Home welfare:

-(b+c+d)

  This loss is larger than a tariff.

It is thought rent seeking is worse in developing countries.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 110 of 136

Import Quotas

3.

 Auctioning the Quota The government of the importing country to auction off the quota licenses.

 In a well-organized, competitive auction, the revenue collected should exactly equal the value of the rents.

Fall in consumer surplus

-(a+b+c+d)

Rise in producer surplus Auction revenue earned at Home

Net effect on Home welfare:

+a +c

-(b+d)

 This is the same loss as the tariff.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 111 of 136

Auctioning Import Quotas in Australia and New Zealand

• • • APPLICATION During the 1980s, Australia and New Zealand both auctioned the quota licenses to import specific goods.

Table 8.3 shows the value of imports covered by quotas curing 1981 –1987.

In 1988, New Zealand announced plans to phase out import quotas as part of a liberalization of trade, and all quota licenses were eliminated by 1992.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 112 of 136

Auctioning Import Quotas in Australia and New Zealand

• • • APPLICATION Table 8.3 also shows the value of bids for the quota licenses.

 These are estimates of rents.

If we take the ratio of the value of bids to the value of imports covered by the quota, we obtain an estimate of the tariff equivalent to the quota.

 These are shown in the final column of table 8.3

Since there was no penalty from not following through, some firms decided not to purchase the licenses after all.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 113 of 136

Auctioning Import Quotas in Australia and New Zealand

APPLICATION

Table 8.3

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 114 of 136

Auctioning Import Quotas in Australia and New Zealand

• • • APPLICATION The government therefore did not collect all the winning bids as revenue.

For those that did buy their licenses, they could be resold and some were at much higher prices.

This makes it appear that the government was not collecting all of the rents in area c.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 115 of 136

Import Quotas

4.

  “Voluntary” Export Restraint The importing country can give authority for implementing the quota to the exporting government.

This is often called a “voluntary” export restraint (VER) or a “voluntary” restraint agreement (VRA).   In the 1980s the U.S. used this type of arrangement to restrict imports of Japanese automobiles.

The Japanese government told each Japanese firm how much it could export to the U.S.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 116 of 136

Import Quotas

• With VERs, quota rents are earned by foreign producers, making Home welfare: Fall in consumer surplus Rise in producer surplus

Net effect on Home welfare:

-(a+b+c+d) +a

-(b+c+d)

• • This is a higher net loss than with a tariff.

Why would an importing country do this?

 It is typically political —the exporting country is less likely to retaliate since they gain the area c.

 This can often avoid a tariff or quota war.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 117 of 136

Import Quotas

• Costs of Import Quotas in the U.S.

 Table 8.4 presents some estimates of Home deadweight losses and quota rents for some major U.S. quotas in the 1980’s.

 In all cases except Dairy, the rents were earned by Foreign exporters.

  Adding up the costs in the table, the total U.S. deadweight loss due to these quotas ranged from $8 – $12 billion annually.

Quota rents transferred another $7 –$17 billion to foreigners.

 Some, but not all, of these costs are relevant today since many of the quotas are no longer in place.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 118 of 136

Table 8.4

Import Quotas

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 119 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

• • • APPLICATION One of the principles of GATT was that countries should not use quotas to restrict imports.

The MFA was a major exception to that which allowed the industrialized countries to restrict imports of textile and apparel products from the developing countries.

Organized under GATT, importing countries could join the MFA and arrange quotas bilaterally or unilaterally.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 120 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

• • • • APPLICATION While the amount of the quotas was occasionally revised upward, they did not keep up with the increasing ability of new supplying countries to sell.

Under the Uruguay round of WTO, developing countries were able to negotiate an end to this system of import quotas.

Given that China was a large supplier of textiles, the expiration of the MFA meant that China could export as much as it wanted – or so it thought.

Some developing countries and large producers in importing countries were concerned with the potential of Chinese exports on their economies.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 121 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

• APPLICATION Growth in Exports from China   Immediately after January 1, 2005, exports of textiles and apparel from China grew rapidly.

In 2005, China’s textile and apparel imports to the U.S. rose by more than 40% compared to 2004.

 Figure 8.10 (a) shows the change in the value of exports of textiles and apparel from different countries. Note China.

 The increases from China came at the expense of some higher-cost exporters, some of whose exports to the U.S. declined by 10 to 20%. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 122 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

APPLICATION

Figure 8.10

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 123 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

• • • APPLICATION Panel (b) of figure 8.10 shows the percentage change in the prices of textiles and apparel products from each country, depending on whether the products were subject to the MFA quota before January 1, 2005, or not.

China had the largest drop in the prices from 2004 to 2005.

Many other countries had a substantial fall in their prices due to the end of the MFA quota.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 124 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

APPLICATION

Figure 8.10

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 125 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

• APPLICATION Welfare Cost of the MFA  Given the drop in prices in 2005, it is possible to estimate the welfare loss due to the MFA.

 Quota rents were earned by foreign exporting firms, giving a welfare loss to Home of area

(b+c+d)

shown in figure 8.9 previously  Using the price drops from figure 8.10

(b+c+d),

the U.S. is estimated at $6.5 to $16.2 billion in 2005 from the MFA.

 Averaging out all losses and dividing among households gives an estimate of $100 per household, or 7% of total annual spending on apparel.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 126 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

• APPLICATION Import Quality    There was also an interesting pattern to the price drops: the price dropped the most for the lower- priced items.

 An inexpensive T-shirt had a greater drop in price than a more expensively priced item.

U.S. demand shifted towards the lower-priced items imported from China: there was “quality downgrading” in the exports from China.

When a quota like the MFA is applied, there is an effect on quality.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 127 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

• APPLICATION Import Quality      Remember that quotas are set on the

quantity

, not the

quality

of items that are imported.

This means that exporting countries have an incentive to upgrade the quality of the product.

Selling a higher value good for the same quantity will still meet the quota limit but will bring more money back home.

MFAs bring “quality upgrading” in the exports Similarly, when the MFA is removed, you will see “quality downgrading.” 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 128 of 136

China and the Multifibre Arrangement

• APPLICATION Reaction of the United States and Europe  The EU threatened to impose new quotas on Chinese exports.

 In response, China agreed on June 11, 2005 to ”voluntarily” restrict exports limiting the growth of textile exports to about 10% per year through the end of 2008.

 The U.S. had the ability to negotiate a new system of quotas because China had joined the WTO in 2001.

 The U.S. deal limited growth to 7.5% until 2008.

2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 129 of 136

Conclusions

• • A tariff on imports is the most commonly used trade policy tool.

First considered a small country with no effect on world price.

 The price faced by consumers and producers in the importing country will rise by the full amount of the tariff.

 There is a drop in consumer surplus, a rise in producer surplus, and the government collects revenue.

 Results in net loss for the importing country.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 130 of 136

Conclusions

• • Why are tariffs used?

 Easy way for governments to raise revenue, especially in developing countries.

 The government might care more about protecting firms than avoiding loses for consumers.

 The small-country assumption may not hold in practice —countries may be large enough to gain from a tariff.

If a country is large enough, they can have an effect on the world price.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 131 of 136

Conclusions

•  In this case, prices rise by less than the full amount of the tariff.

 It is therefore possible for a small tariff to generate welfare gains for the importing country.

 This does come at the expense of the foreign exporters —“beggar thy neighbor” policy.

 Overall there are still world losses.

Countries also may choose quotas, which restrict the quantity of imports into a country.

  WTO has tried to restrict the use of quotas.

Deletion of MFA quotas still lead to new quotas against China.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 132 of 136

Conclusions

• Import quotas lead to similar welfare effects of tariffs.

 Increase domestic price with loss for consumers and gains for producers.

 Quota rents instead of guaranteed government revenues.

 If resources are wasted by firms to gains rents, additional deadweight losses are incurred.

 It is more common for foreign exporters to earn the quota rents – VER.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 133 of 136

Key Points

1.

2.

3.

The government of a country a can use laws and regulations, called trade policies, to affect international trade flows.

The rules governing grade policies in most countries are outlined by the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), now the World Trade Organization (WTO). In a small country, the world price faced is fixed, so the price faced by consumers and producers will rise by the full amount of the tariff.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 134 of 136

Key Points

4.

5.

6.

7.

8.

The use of a tariff by a small importing country always leads to a net loss in welfare.

In a large country, the change in imports from a tariff will lower world price so the price to the importing country does not rise by the full amount of the tariff.

The use of a tariff for a large country can lead to a net gain in welfare.

The optimal tariff is the tariff amount that maximizes welfare for the importer.

The formula for the optimal tariff shows that it depends inversely on the foreign export supply elasticity.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 135 of 136

Key Points

9.

Import quotas restrict the quantity of a particular import, thereby increasing the domestic price, benefiting domestic production and creating a benefit for those who are allowed to import the quantity allotted. Benefits are quota rents.

10.

Assuming perfectly competitive markets for goods, quotas are similar to tariffs since the restriction in the amount imported leads to a higher domestic price. Rents, however, can be earned by the foreign country and can create additional dead weight losses.

© 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 136 of 136