投影片 1 - ndhu.edu.tw

Download Report

Transcript 投影片 1 - ndhu.edu.tw

Appendix 4.A
A Formal Model of
Consumption and Saving
Micro-foundation of Macro
Abel & Bernake: Macro Ch3
Varian: Micro Ch10
1
Optimization over time
Max U(C, C f )
st a f  (1  r )(a  Y  C )
C f  a f Y f
Cf
Yf
C (
)  a Y  (
)
1 r
1 r

Current income Y, future income Yf : Endowment point: (a+Y, Yf)
initial wealth a, wealth at beginning of future period af ;
Choice variables: C = current consumption; Cf = future consumption
Slope of lifetime BC = -(1+r)
2
Figure 4.A.1 The budget line
3
Present-Value Budget Constraint (PVBC)



Present value of lifetime wealth:
PVLW = a+ Y + Yf/(1+r)
Present value of lifetime consumption:
PVLC = C + Cf/(1+r)
(4.A.2)
The budget constraint means PVLC = PVLW
C + Cf/(1+r) =a+ Y + Yf/(1+r)
(4.A.3)
Slope of PVBC≡ (△Cf/△C)= -(1+r)
Price of current consumption=(1+r):△Cf = -(1+r) △C
4
Consumer Preferences: Indifference Curves


A person is equally happy at any point on an indifference curve
3 important properties of indifference curves
 Slope downward from left to right:
Less consumption in one period requires more consumption in
the other period to keep utility unchanged
 Indifference curves that are farther up and to the right
represent higher levels of utility,
because more consumption is preferred to less
 Indifference curves are bowed toward the origin,
because people have a consumption-smoothing motive,
they prefer consuming equal amounts in each period rather than
consuming a lot one period and little the other period
5
Figure 4.A.2 Indifference curves
6
The Optimal Level of Consumption

Optimal consumption point:
the budget line is tangent to an indifference curve
(Fig. 4.A.3)
Tangency condition: ?
7
Fig 4.A.3 The optimal consumption combination
8
Saving (S), a lender or a borrower

S≡Y-C
If C=Y, S=0
If C<Y, S>0
If C>Y, S<0
 af=
0, C=a+Y: no-borrowing, no-lending
af>0, C< a+Y: lender, with interest income
af< 0, C< a+Y: borrower, with interest payment
9
Income Effect (IE) or Wealth Effect

When income or wealth (PVLW) increases,
PVBC shifts outward, the opportunity set increases,
the demand for normal goods (C and Cf ) increases.
a↑, Y↑, Yf ↑: PVLW↑
 C↑ and Cf ↑
10
Comparative Statics: △a, △Y, △Yf

An increase in wealth: a↑
 Increases PVLW, so LRBC shifts out parallel to old BC.
 with consumption smoothing, both current and future
consumption increase
 IE: a↑ PVLW↑, C↑, Cf↑ (Y is unchanged, S:↓)

An increase in current income: Y ↑ (Fig. 4.A.4)
Y↑ IE: C↑, Cf ↑ (S↑)

An increase in future income: Yf ↑
Yf↑ IE: C↑, Cf ↑ (S↓)
11
Fig 4.A.4 An increase in income or wealth
12
Permanent vs. temporary increase in income

Different types of changes in income
 Temporary increase in income:
Y rises and Yf is unchanged
?
 Permanent
increase in income:
Both Y and Yf rise
?
13
The permanent income theory

This distinction made by Milton Friedman in the 1950s
and is known as the permanent income theory
 Permanent changes in income lead to much larger
changes in consumption
 Thus permanent income changes are mostly consumed,
while temporary income changes are mostly saved
14
Life-Cycle Model



developed by Franco Modigliani and associates in the 1950s
 Patterns of income, consumption, and saving over an
individual’s lifetime (Fig. 4.A.5)
Real income steadily rises over time until near retirement;
at retirement, income drops sharply
Lifetime pattern of consumption is much smoother than the
income pattern.
15
Figure 4.A.5
Life-cycle consumption,
income, and saving
hump-shaped of Y, S
16
Ricardian equivalence: two-period model


Suppose the government reduces taxes by 100 in the
current period, r = 10%,
and taxes will be increased by 110 in the future period
Cf
Y f T f
C (
)  a  (Y  T )  (
)
1 r
1 r
T  0, T f  (1  r )T  0
Then the PVLW is unchanged, and no change in C.
Or ?


17
Fiscal policy:
△T<0 (a lump-sum tax↓ )  △Sd
Assume closed economy: NFP=0,
Assume TR=INT=0 for simplicity
 S= Y + NFP– C – G
Spvt= Y + NFP – T + TR + INT – C
Sgovt =T – TR – INT – G
???
18
Fiscal policy: △G>0  △Sd
19
Excess sensitivity of consumption

Generally, life cycle or permanent income theory
have been supported by looking at real-world data
 But data shows some excess sensitivity of
consumption to changes in current income
 This could be due to short-sighted behavior
 Or it could be due to borrowing constraints
20
Borrowing constraints



If a person wants to borrow and can’t, the borrowing
constraint is binding
A consumer with a binding borrowing constraint spends all
income and wealth on consumption.
 So an increase in income or wealth will be entirely spent
on consumption as well
 This causes consumption to be excessively sensitive to
current income changes
Perhaps 20% to 50% of the U.S. population faces binding
borrowing constraints.
21
Comparative statics: change in r

r↑(Fig. 4.A.6)


one point on the old BC is also on the new BC:
the no-borrowing, no-lending point
Slope of new budget line is steeper
22
Fig 4.A.6 The effect of an increase in the real interest
rate on the budget line
23
Intertemporal substitution effect (ISE)
r↑makes future consumption cheaper relative to
current consumption
 use cheaper Cf to substitute more costly C,
C↓(S↑), Cf ↑

24
Fig 4.A.7 The substitution effect
of an increase in the real interest rate
25
Income Effect (IE)
For a person consume at no-borrowing, no-lending
point,
r↑ no IE
 If the person originally a lender,
r↑ positive IE  C↑, Cf ↑
 If the person originally a borrower,
r↑ negative IE  C↓, Cf ↓

26
Δr: Total effect =ISE +IE

IE and ISE together
 If a person consumes at no-borrowing, no-lending
point (Fig. 4.A.7),
?
 For a lender, (Fig. 4.A.8)
?
 For a borrower,
?
27
Fig 4.A.8 An increase in the real interest rate with both
an income effect and a substitution effect
28
Δr  aggregate saving

The effect on aggregate saving of r↑ is ambiguous
theoretically.
 Empirical research suggests that saving ↑
(Saving function is positively-sloped)
 But the effect is small
29
Temporary vs. Permanent increase in wage
Optimization over time (Ch3)
Max U(C, L, Cf, Lf)
 ISE between current C and future Cf
ISE between current L and future Lf
 If temporary w↑: strong ISE + weak IE
ISE > IE => L↓, h ↑
 If permanent w↑ : weak ISE + strong IE
ISE < IE => L ↑, h ↓
 Empirical evidence support the implication.
30