Transcript Chapter 14: Externalities, Public Goods, Imperfect
Externalities
• An
externality
is a cost or benefit resulting from some activity or transaction that is imposed or bestowed upon parties outside the activity or transaction. Sometimes called
spillovers
or
neighborhood effects.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Externalities
• When
external costs
are not considered in economic decisions, we may engage in activities or produce products are not “worth it.” • When
external benefits
are not considered, we may fail to do things that are indeed “worth it.” The result is an inefficient allocation of resources.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Marginal Social Cost and Marginal-Cost Pricing
•
Marginal social cost (MSC)
is the total cost to society of producing an additional unit of a good or service.
•
MSC
is equal to the sum of the marginal costs of producing the product and the correctly measured damage costs involved in the process of production.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Marginal Social Cost and Marginal-Cost Pricing
• At q*, marginal social cost exceeds the price paid by consumers. Output is too high. Market price takes into account only part of the full cost of producing the good.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Private Choices and External Effects
•
Marginal private cost
(
MPC
) is the amount that a consumer pays to consume an additional unit of a particular good.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Private Choices and External Effects
•
Marginal benefit
(
MB
) is the benefit derived from each successive hour of music, or the maximum amount of money Harry is willing to pay for an additional hour of music.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Private Choices and External Effects
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e • Harry would play the stereo until
MB
=
MPC
, or eight hours.
• However, this result would be socially inefficient because Harry does not consider the cost imposed on Jake.
Karl Case, Ray Fair
Private Choices and External Effects
•
Marginal damage cost
(
MDC
) is the additional harm done by increasing the level of an externality producing activity by one unit.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Private Choices and External Effects
•
Marginal social
cost (MSC)
is the total cost to society of playing an additional hour of music.
• Playing the stereo beyond more than five hours is inefficient because the benefits to Harry are less than the social cost for every hour above five.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Internalizing Externalities
• A tax per unit equal to
MDC
is imposed on the firm. The firm will weigh the tax, and thus the damage costs, in its decisions.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
The Coase Theorem
• Government need not be involved in every case of externality.
• Private bargains and negotiations are likely to lead to an efficient solution in many social damage cases without any government involvement at all. This argument is referred to as the
Coase Theorem
.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
The Coase Theorem
• Three conditions must be satisfied for Coase’s solution to work: • Basic rights at issue must be assigned and clearly understood.
• There are no impediments to bargaining.
• Only a few people can be involved.
• Bargaining will bring the contending parties to the right solution regardless of where rights are initially assigned.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Indirect and Direct Regulations
• Taxes, subsidies, legal rules, and public auction are all methods of
indirect
regulation designed to induce firms and households to weigh the social costs of their actions against the benefits.
•
Direct
regulation includes legislation that regulates activities that, for example, are likely to harm the environment.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Public Goods
•
Public goods
(
social
or
collective goods
) are goods that are nonrival in consumption and/or their benefits are nonexcludable.
• Public goods have characteristics that make it difficult for the private sector to produce them profitably (market failure).
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
The Characteristics of Public Goods
• A good is
nonrival in consumption
when A’s consumption of it does not interfere with B’s consumption of it. The benefits of the good are collective —they accrue to everyone.
• A good is
nonexcludable
if, once produced, no one can be excluded from enjoying its benefits. The good cannot be withheld from those that don’t pay for it.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
The Characteristics of Public Goods
• Because people can enjoy the benefits of public goods whether they pay for them or not, they are usually unwilling to pay for them. This is referred to as the
free-rider problem
.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
The Characteristics of Public Goods
• The
drop-in-the-bucket problem
is another problem intrinsic to public goods: The good or service is usually so costly that its provision generally does not depend on whether or not any single person pays.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
The Characteristics of Public Goods
• Consumers acting in their own self interest have no incentive to contribute voluntarily to the production of public goods.
• Most people do not find room in their budgets for many voluntary payments. The economic incentive is missing.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Public Provision of Public Goods
• Public provision does not imply public production of public goods.
• Problems of public provision include frequent dissatisfaction. Individuals don’t get to choose the quantity they want to buy —it is a collective purchase. We are all dissatisfied! © 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Optimal Provision of Public Goods
• With private goods, consumers decide what quantity to buy; market demand is the sum of those quantities at each price.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Optimal Provision of Public Goods
• With public goods, there is only one level of output, and consumers are willing to pay different amounts for each level.
• The market demand for a public good is the vertical sum of the amounts that individual households are willing to pay for each potential level of output.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Optimal Production of a Public Good
•
Optimal production of a public good
means producing as long as society’s total willingness to pay per unit D (A+B) is greater than the marginal cost of producing the good.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Local Provision of Public Goods
• According to the
Tiebout hypothesis
, an efficient mix of public goods is produced when local land/housing prices and taxes come to reflect consumer preferences just as they do in the market for private goods.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Imperfect Information and Adverse Selection
• Most voluntary exchanges are efficient, but in the presence of imperfect information, not all exchanges are efficient.
•
Adverse selection
can occur when a buyer or seller enters into an exchange with another party who has more information.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Moral Hazard
•
Moral hazard
arises when one party to a contract passes the cost of his or her behavior on to the other party to the contract.
• The moral hazard problem is an information problem, in which contracting parties cannot always determine the future behavior of the person with whom they are contracting.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Market Solutions
• As with any other good, there is an efficient quantity of information production.
• Like consumers, profit-maximizing firms will gather information as long as the marginal benefits from continued search are greater than the marginal costs.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Government Solutions
• Information is nonrival in consumption.
• When information is very costly for individuals to collect and disperse, it may be cheaper for government to produce it once for everybody.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Social Choice
•
Social choice
is the problem of deciding what society wants. The process of adding up individual preferences to make a choice for society as a whole.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
The Impossibility Theorem
• The
impossibility theorem
is a proposition demonstrated by Kenneth Arrow showing that no system of aggregating individual preferences into social decisions will always yield consistent, nonarbitrary results.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
The Impossibility Theorem
Preferences of Three Top University Officials
VP1 prefers A to B and B to C. VP2 prefers B to C and C to A. The dean prefers C to A and A to B.
OPTION A OPTION B OPTION C Hire more faculty No change Reduce the size of the faculty
Ranking 1 2 3 X X X
VP1
X X X
VP2 Dean
X X X • If A beast B, and B beats C, how can C beat A? The results are inconsistent.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
The Voting Paradox
• The
voting paradox
is a simple demonstration of how majority-rule voting can lead to seemingly contradictory and inconsistent results. A commonly cited illustration of inconsistency described in the impossibility theorem.
Results of Voting on University’s Plans: The Voting Paradox Vote
A versus B B versus C C versus A
VP1
A B A
VOTES OF: VP2
B B C a A > B is read “A is preferred to B.”
Dean
A C C
Result a
A wins: A > B B wins: B > C C wins: C > A © 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair
Rent-Seeking Revisited
• There are reasons to believe that government attempts to produce the right goods and services in the right quantities efficiently may fail.
• The existence of an “optimal” level of public-goods production does not guarantee that governments will achieve it.
© 2002 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 6/e Karl Case, Ray Fair