Transcript Document

Determination of
Forward and Futures Prices
Chapter 3
Chapter Outline
3.1 Investment assets vs. consumption assets
3.2 Short selling
3.3 Measuring interest rates
3.4 Assumptions and notation
3.5 Forward price for an investment asset
3.6 Known income
3.7 Known yield
Chapter Outline (continued)
3.8 Valuing forward contracts
3.9 Are forward prices and futures prices equal?
3.10 Stock index futures
3.11 Forward and futures contracts on currencies
3.12 Futures on commodities
3.13 Cost of carry
3.14 Delivery options
3.15 Futures prices and the expected future spot
price
Summary
3.1 Investment assets vs. consumption
assets
• Investment assets are assets held by significant
numbers of people purely for investment purposes
(Examples: gold, silver)
• Consumption assets are assets held primarily for
consumption (Examples: copper, oil)
• We will see later that we can use arbitrage
arguments to determine the forward and futures
prices of an investment asset from its spot price
and other observable market variables.
• We cannot do this for consumption assets.
3.2 Short Selling (Page 41-42)
• Short selling involves selling securities you
do not own.
• Your broker borrows the securities from
another client and sells them in the market in
the usual way.
• At some stage you must buy the securities
back so they can be replaced in the account of
the client.
• You must pay dividends and other benefits the
owner of the securities receives.
Short Selling
(continued)
• If you believe that a stock is going to go up
in price, go long.
• If you are correct, you will “buy low and
sell high”.
• If you believe that a stock is going to go
down in price, go short.
• If you are correct, you will “sell high and
buy low ”.
An Example of an Short Sale
Open Market
$12,000
September 1
$8,000
October 1
100 shares
October 1
100 shares
September 1
Broker
$12,000
Sept 1
100 shares 100 shares
October 1 September 1
$8,000
October 1
Short
Seller
Share
holder
Stock Price
SEPTEMBER 1
OCTOBER 1
$120
$80
3.3 Measuring interest rates
• The compounding frequency used
for an interest rate is the unit of
measurement
• The difference between quarterly
and annual compounding is
analogous to the difference between
miles and kilometers
Continuous Compounding
(Page 43)
• In the limit as we compound more and more
frequently we obtain continuously
compounded interest rates
• $100 grows to $100eRT when invested at a
continuously compounded rate R for time T
• $100 received at time T discounts to $100e-RT
at time zero when the continuously
compounded discount rate is R
Conversion Formulas
(Page 44)
Define
Rc : continuously compounded rate
Rm: same rate with compounding m times per
year
Rm 

Rc  m ln 1 


m 


Rm  m e Rc / m  1
3.4 Assumptions and notation
• Assumptions:
– No no transactions costs
– Homogeneous tax rates on net trading profits
– Everyone can borrow and lend at the same riskfree rate
– Market participants can take advantage of
arbitrage opportunities.
3.4 Assumptions and notation
• Notation:
S0: Spot price today
F0: Futures or forward price today
T: Time until delivery date
r: Risk-free interest rate per annum,
expressed with continuous
compounding, for maturity T
3.5 Forward price for an investment asset
• The easiest forward contract to value is one
written on an investment asset that provides
the holder with no income.
Gold Example (From Chapter 1)
• For gold
F0 = S0(1 + r )T
(assuming no storage costs)
• If r is compounded continuously instead of
annually
F0 = S0erT
Extension of the Gold Example
(Page 46, equation 3.5)
• Suppose gold is currently $300 per ounce
and the risk-free rate is 5% p.a.
• A 6-month forward contract on gold will
have a price F0 = S0erT = $300e..05*.5 = $307.59
0
T
S0
S0erT
• If F0  $307.59 there will be an arbitrage
Extension of the Gold Example
(Page 46, equation 3.5)
• Suppose gold is currently $300 per ounce and
the risk-free rate is 5% p.a. and the 6-month
forward contract on gold has a price F0 = $310
0
•borrow $300
•Buy one ounce of gold
•Short a forward contract on
one ounce of gold
T
•Sell one ounce of gold for
$310 through the forward
contract
•repay $300 loan with $307.59
Extension of the Gold Example
(Page 46, equation 3.5)
• Suppose gold is currently $300 per ounce and
the risk-free rate is 5% p.a. and the 6-month
forward contract on gold has a price F0 = $305
0
•Sell one ounce of gold
•Invest the $300 at 5%
•Take a long position in a
forward contract on one ounce
of gold
T
•Collect $307.59 on the $300
investment
•Buy one ounce of gold for
$305 through the forward
contract
3.6 Known income
• Consider a long forward contract to
purchase a coupon-bearing bond issued by
Advanced Micro Devices.
• The forward contract matures in one year.
• Assume today’s date is July 2nd, 2002
Cash Flows of the Bond
In 1994, Advanced Micro Devices issued a 6% semi-annual
coupon bond in 1995 that matures in 2005.
$30 is payable every January 1 and July 1
The face value is $1,000
The historical and future cash flows look like this
$30
01/01/95
$30
07/01/95
$30
01/01/96
$30
07/01/96
$30
01/01/97
…
$30
07/01/04
$1,030
01/01/05
Cash Flows of the Bond
If you were to buy this bond July 2, 2002, your cash flows
would look like this:
$974.67 $30
07/02/02
01/01/03
$30
07/01/03
$30
01/01/04
$30
07/01/04
$1,030
01/01/05
If the discount rate is 7% per annum continuously compounded
PV  $30e .07.5  $30e .07.1  $30e .071.5  $30e .072  $1,030e .072.5
PV  $28.97  $27.97  $27.01  $26.08  $864.64
PV  $974.67
Cash Flows of the Forward Contract
The forward contract on this bond calls for delivery of the
bond on 7/02/03
$984.27 $30
07/02/02
01/01/03
07/01/03
01/01/04
$30
07/01/04
If the discount rate is still 7% per annum continuously
compounded the bond will then be worth $984.27
PV  $30e .07.5  $30e .07.1  $1,030e .071.5
PV  $28.97  $27.97  $927.33
PV  $984.27
$1,030
01/01/05
Cash Flows of the Bond and forward.
Another way to find the forward price is to consider the
value of the bond on July 02,2002 along with the present
value of the coupon payments


F0  $974.67  30e .07.5  $30e .07.1 e .071
F0  $984.27
$974.67 $30
07/02/02
01/01/03
$30
07/01/03
$30
01/01/04
$30
07/01/04
$1,030
01/01/05
When an Investment Asset Provides a
Known Dollar Income (page 48, equation 3.6)
F0 = (S0 – I )erT
where I is the present value of the
income

F0  $974.67  30e
.07.5
 $30e
F0  $984.27
.07.1
e
.071
3.7 Known yield
• Consider a situation where the underlying
asset provides a known yield rather than a
known cash income.
When an Investment Asset Provides a
Known Yield
(Page 49, equation 3.7)
F0 = S0 e(r–q )T
where q is the average yield during the life of
the contract (expressed with continuous
compounding)
3.8 Valuing forward contracts
• Suppose that
K is delivery price in a forward contract
F0 is forward price that would apply to the
contract today
• The value of a long forward contract, ƒ, is
ƒ = (F0 – K )e–rT
• Similarly, the value of a short forward contract is
(K – F0 )e–rT
Valuing a Forward Contract
• Let us revisit our previous example of the
forward contract on the AMD bond.
• Suppose that we had taken a long position in
the contract on July 2, 2002 at $984.27
• Ten minutes later, interest rates have risen to
8% per annum.
• Have we made money or lost money?
The value of a long forward contract, ƒ, is
ƒ = (F0 – K )e–rT
Valuing a Forward Contract
PV  $30e .08.5  $30e .08.1  $1,030e .081.5
PV  $28.82  $27.69  $913.53
PV  $970.05 $30
07/02/02
01/01/03
07/01/03
01/01/04
$30
07/01/04
$1,030
01/01/05
We have agreed to pay $984.27 on July 2, 2003 for an asset
that will be worth $970.05.
This will be a loss of $14.22 at expiry.
The present value of that loss is $14.22e-.08×.5 =$13.13
ƒ = (F0 – K )e–rT
= ($970.05 – 984.27 )e–.08 = $13.13
3.9 Are forward prices and futures prices
equal?
• Forward and futures prices are usually assumed to be
the same. When interest rates are uncertain they are,
in theory, slightly different:
• A strong positive correlation between interest rates
and the asset price implies the futures price is
slightly higher than the forward price
• A strong negative correlation implies the reverse
• In practice, we also must consider the probability of
counterparty default, taxes, transactions costs, and
the treatment of margins.
• For long-lived contracts like Eurodollar futures
contracts with maturities as long as ten years, it
would be dangerous to ignore the differences.
3.10 Stock index futures
• A stock index can be viewed as an
investment asset paying a dividend yield
• The futures price and spot price relationship
is therefore
F0 = S0 e(r–q )T
where q is the dividend yield on the
portfolio represented by the index
Stock Index
(continued)
• For the formula to be true it is important
that the index represent an investment
asset
• In other words, changes in the index
must correspond to changes in the value
of a tradable portfolio
• The Nikkei index viewed as a dollar
number does not represent an investment
asset
Index Arbitrage
• When F0>S0e(r-q)T an arbitrageur buys the
stocks underlying the index and sells futures
• When F0<S0e(r-q)T an arbitrageur buys
futures and shorts or sells the stocks
underlying the index
Index Arbitrage
(continued)
• Index arbitrage involves simultaneous
trades in futures and many different stocks
• Very often a computer is used to generate
the trades
• Occasionally (e.g., on Black Monday)
simultaneous trades are not possible and
the theoretical no-arbitrage relationship
between F0 and S0 does not hold
3.11 Futures and Forwards on Currencies
(Page 55-58)
• A foreign currency is analogous to a security
providing a dividend yield
• The continuous dividend yield is the foreign
risk-free interest rate
• It follows that if rf is the foreign risk-free
interest rate
F0  S0e
( r rf ) T
Futures and Forwards on Currencies
• This equilibrium condition is perhaps more
widely known as interest rate parity.
Interest Rate Parity Defined
• IRP is an arbitrage condition.
• If IRP did not hold, then it would be
possible for an astute trader to make
unlimited amounts of money exploiting the
arbitrage opportunity.
• Since we don’t typically observe persistent
arbitrage conditions, we can safely assume
that IRP holds.
IRP and Covered Interest Arbitrage
If IRP failed to hold, an arbitrage would exist.
It’s easiest to see this in the form of an
example.
Consider the following set of foreign and
domestic interest rates and spot and forward
exchange rates.
Spot exchange rate
360-day forward rate
S($/£) = $1.25/£
F360($/£) = $1.20/£
U.S. discount rate
r$ = 7.10%
British discount rate
r£ =
11.18%
IRP and Covered Interest Arbitrage
A trader with $1,000 to invest could invest in
the U.S., in one year his investment will be
worth $1,073.58 = $1,000e.071
Alternatively, this trader could exchange
$1,000 for £800 at the prevailing spot rate,
(note that £800 = $1,000÷$1.25/£) invest
£800 at i£ = 11.18% for one year to achieve
£894.65. Translate £894.65 back into
dollars at F360($/£) = $1.20/£, the £892.48
will be exactly $1,073.58.
IRP and Covered Interest Arbitrage
According to IRP only one 360-day forward
rate,
F360($/£), can exist. It must be the case that
F360($/£) = $1.20/£
Why?
If F360($/£)  $1.20/£, an astute trader could
make money with one of the following
strategies:
Arbitrage Strategy I
If F360($/£) > $1.20/£
i. Borrow $1,000 at t = 0 at i$ = 7.1%.
ii. Exchange $1,000 for £800 at the prevailing spot
rate, (note that £800 = $1,000÷$1.25/£) invest £800
at 11.18% (i£) for one year to achieve £894.65
iii. Translate £894.65 back into dollars, if
F360($/£) > $1.20/£ , £94.65 will be more than
enough to repay your dollar obligation of $1,073.58.
Arbitrage Strategy II
If F360($/£) < $1.20/£
i. Borrow £800 at t = 0 at i£= 11.18% .
ii. Exchange £800 for $1,000 at the
prevailing spot rate, invest $1,000 at 7.1%
for one year to achieve $1,073.58.
iii. Translate $1,073.58 back into pounds, if
F360($/£) < $1.20/£ , $1,073.58 will be more
than enough to repay your £ obligation of
£894.65.
3.12 Futures on commodities
F0  S0 e(r+u )T
where u is the storage cost per unit time as
a percent of the asset value.
Alternatively,
F0  (S0+U )erT
where U is the present value of the storage
costs.
3.13 The Cost of Carry (Page 60)
• The cost of carry, c, is the storage cost plus
the interest costs less the income earned
• For an investment asset F0 = S0ecT
• For a consumption asset F0  S0ecT
• The convenience yield on the consumption
asset, y, is defined so that
F0 = S0 e(c–y )T
3.14 Delivery options
• Whereas a forward contract normally
specifies that delivery is to take place on a
particular day, a futures contract often
allows the party with the short position to
choose to deliver at any time during a
certain period.
• This option introduces a complication into
the determination of futures prices.
3.14 Delivery options
• If the futures price is an increasing function
of the time to maturity, it can be seen from
F0 = S0 e(c–y )T
that c > y, so that the benefits from hoding
the asset are less than the risk-free rate, so
the short will probably deliver as soon as
possible
3.15 Futures Prices & Expected Future
Spot Prices (Page 61)
• Suppose k is the expected return
required by investors on an asset
• We can invest F0e–r T now to get ST back
at maturity of the futures contract
• This shows that
F0 = E (ST )e(r–k )T
46
Futures Prices & Future Spot Prices
(continued)
• If the asset has
– no systematic risk, then
k = r and F0 is an unbiased
estimate of ST
– positive systematic risk, then
k > r and F0 < E (ST )
– negative systematic risk, then
k < r and F0 > E (ST )
Summary
• Most of the time, the futures price of a
contract with a certain delivery date can be
considered to be the same as the forward
price for a contract with the same delivery
date.
• It is convenient to divide futures contracts
into two categories
– Those written on investment assets
– Those written on consumption assets
Summary
• In the case of investment assets, we
considered three situations
– The underlying asset provides no income
– The asset provides a known dollar income
– The asset provides a known yield