Behaviouralizing Finance

Download Report

Transcript Behaviouralizing Finance

Behaviouralizing Finance
CARISMA
February 2010
Hersh Shefrin
Mario L. Belotti Professor of Finance
Santa Clara University
Outline
• Paradigm shift.
• Strengths and weaknesses of
behavioural approach.
• Combining rigour of neoclassical
finance and the realistic psychologicallybased assumptions of behavioural
finance.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
2
Quantitative Finance
• Behaviouralizing
─Beliefs & preferences
─Portfolio selection theory
─Asset pricing theory
─Corporate finance
─Approach to financial market regulation
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
3
Weaknesses in
Behavioural Approach
• Preferences.
─ Prospect theory, SP/A, regret.
─ Disposition effect.
•
•
•
•
•
Cross section.
Long-run dynamics.
Contingent claims (SDF: 0 or 2?)
Sentiment.
Representative investor.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
4
Conference Participants
Examples
• Continuous time model of portfolio selection with
behavioural preferences.
─ He and Zhou (2009), Zhou, De Georgi
• Prospect theory and equilibrium
─ De Giorgi, Hens, and Rieger (2009).
• Prospect theory and disposition effect
─ Hens and Vlcek (2005), Barberis and Xiong (2009), Kaustia
(2009).
• Long term survival.
─ Blume and Easley in Hens and Schenk-Hoppé (2008).
• Term structure of interest rates.
─ Xiong and Yan (2009).
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
5
Beliefs
• Change of measure techniques.
─Excessive optimism.
─Overconfidence.
─Ambiguity aversion.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
6
Example:
Change of Measure is Log-linear
• Typical for a variance preserving, right
shift in mean for a normally distributed
variable.
• Shape of log-change of measure
function?
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
7
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
99.84%
99.50%
99.16%
98.82%
8
-0.4
-0.6
-0.8
Consumption Growth Rate g (Gross)
106.19%
105.82%
105.46%
105.10%
104.74%
104.38%
104.03%
103.67%
103.32%
102.96%
102.61%
102.26%
101.91%
101.56%
101.22%
100.87%
100.53%
100.18%
-0.2
98.48%
98.15%
97.81%
97.48%
97.14%
96.81%
96.48%
96.15%
95.82%
Excessive Optimism
Sentiment Function
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
99.84%
99.50%
99.16%
9
-0.4
-0.6
-0.8
Consumption Growth Rate g (Gross)
106.19%
105.82%
105.46%
105.10%
104.74%
104.38%
104.03%
103.67%
103.32%
102.96%
102.61%
102.26%
101.91%
101.56%
101.22%
100.87%
100.53%
100.18%
-0.2
98.82%
98.48%
98.15%
97.81%
97.48%
97.14%
96.81%
96.48%
96.15%
95.82%
Excessive Pessimism
Sentiment Function
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
Overconfidence
Sentiment Function
0.5
-0.5
-1
-1.5
-2
-2.5
Consumption Growth Rate g (Gross)
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
10
106%
104%
103%
101%
99%
97%
96%
0
Preferences
• Psychological concepts
─Psychophysics in prospect theory.
─Emotions in SP/A theory.
• Inverse S-shaped weighting function,
rank dependent utility.
─Regret.
─Self-control.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
11
Prospect Theory Weighting Function
Based on Hölder Average
Ingersoll Critique
Prospect Theory Weighting Function
1.0
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
0.35
0.4
0.45
0.5
0.55
0.6
Decumulative Probability
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
12
0.65
0.7
0.75
0.8
0.85
0.9
0.95
1
Inverse S in SP/A
Rank Dependent Utility
Functional Decomposition of Decumulative Weighting Function in SP/A Theory
1.2
1.0
h2(D)
0.8
h(D)
0.6
0.4
h1(D)
0.2
0.0
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
D
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
13
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
Prospect Theory
• Tversky-Kahneman
(1992)
Prospect Theory Value Function
6
4
2
─Value function
• piecewise power
function
─Weighting function
• ratio of power
function to Hölder
average
─Editing / Framing
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
9.
5
8
8.
75
6.
5
7.
25
5
5.
75
3.
5
4.
25
2
2.
75
-1
-0
.2
5
0.
5
1.
25
-4
-3
.2
5
-2
.5
-1
.7
5
-7
-6
.2
5
-5
.5
-4
.7
5
-1
0
-9
.2
5
-8
.5
-7
.7
5
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
Gain/loss
Prospect Theory Weighting Function
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0
0.05 0.09 0.14 0.18 0.23 0.27 0.32 0.36 0.41 0.45 0.5 0.54 0.59 0.63 0.68 0.72 0.77 0.81 0.86 0.9 0.95 0.99
Probability
14
SP-Function in SP/A
Rank Dependent Utility
n
SP =  (h(Di)-h(Di+1))u(xi)
i=1
• Utility function u is defined over gains and
losses.
• Lopes and Lopes-Oden model u as linear.
─ suggest mild concavity is more realistic
• Rank dependent utility: h is a weighting function
on decumulative probabilities.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
15
The A in SP/A
• The A in SP/A denotes aspiration.
• Aspiration pertains to a target value  to
which the decision maker aspires.
• The aspiration point might reflect status
quo, i.e., no gain or loss.
• In SP/A theory, aspiration-risk is measured
in terms of the probability
A=Prob{x }
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
16
Objective Function
• In SP/A theory, the decision maker
maximizes an objective function
L(SP,A).
• L is strictly monotone increasing in both
arguments.
• Therefore, there are situations in which
a decision maker is willing to trade off
some SP in exchange for a higher
value of A.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
17
Testing CPT vs. SP/A
Experimental Evidence
• Lopes-Oden report that adding $50
induces a switch from the sure prospect
to the risky prospect.
• Consistent with SP/A theory if A is
germane, but not with CPT.
• Payne (2006) offers similar evidence
that A is critically important, although
his focus is OPT vs. CPT.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
18
Behaviouralizing Portfolios
• Full optimization using behavioural
beliefs and/or preferences.
• What is shape of return profile relative
to the state variable?
• In slides immediately following, dotted
graph corresponds to investor with
average risk aversion.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
19
Baseline: Aggressive Investor With
Unbiased Beliefs
cj/c0 vs. g
1.8
1.6
1.4
1.2
cj/c0
1
cj/c0
g
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
g
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
20
1.
21
1.
19
1.
17
1.
15
1.
13
1.
11
1.
09
1.
07
1.
05
1.
03
1.
01
0.
99
0.
97
0.
95
0.
93
0.
91
0.
89
0.
87
0.
85
0.
83
0.
81
0.
79
0
How Would You Characteize an Investor
Whose Return Profile Has
This Shape?
cj/c0 vs. g
1.4
1.2
1
cj/c0
0.8
cj/c0
g
0.6
0.4
0.2
g
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
21
1.
21
1.
19
1.
17
1.
15
1.
13
1.
11
1.
09
1.
07
1.
05
1.
03
1.
01
0.
99
0.
97
0.
95
0.
93
0.
91
0.
89
0.
87
0.
85
0.
83
0.
81
0.
79
0
Two Choices
• Aggressive underconfidence?
• Aggressive overconfidence?
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
22
CPT With Probability Weights
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
23
CPT With Rank Dependent Weights
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
24
SP/A With Cautious Hope
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
25
Associated Log-Change of Measure
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
26
Caution!
Quasi-Optimization
• Prospect theory was not developed as
a full optimization model.
• It’s a heuristic-based model of choice,
where editing and framing are central.
• It’s a suboptimization model, where
choice heuristics commonly lead to
suboptimal if not dominated acts.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
27
Behaviouralizing
Asset Pricing Theory
• Stochastic discount factor (SDF) is a
state price per unit probability.
• SDF  M = /.
• Price of any one-period security Z is
qZ = Z = E{MZ}
Et[Ri,t+1 Mt+1] = 1
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
28
Graph of SDF
What’s This?
• x-axis is a state
variable like
aggregate
consumption
growth.
• y-axis is M.
• SDF is linear.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
29
How About This?
Logarithmic Case?
• x-axis is a state
variable like logaggregate
consumption
growth.
• y-axis is log-M.
• Relationship is
linear.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
30
Empirical SDF
• Aït-Sahalia and Lo (2000) study
economic VaR for risk management,
and estimate the SDF.
• Rosenberg and Engle (2002) also
estimate the SDF.
• Both use index option data in
conjunction with empirical return
distribution information.
• What does the empirical SDF look like?
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
31
Aït-Sahalia – Lo’s SDF Estimate
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
32
Rosenberg-Engle’s SDF Estimate
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
33
Behavioral Aggregation
• Begin with neoclassical EU model with
CRRA preferences and complete
markets.
• In respect to judgments, markets
aggregate pdfs, not moments.
─Generalized Hölder average theorem.
• In respect to preferences, markets
aggregate coefficients of risk tolerance
(inverse of CRRA).
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
34
Representative Investor Models
• Many asset pricing theorists, from both
neoclassical and behavioral camps,
assume a representative investor in
their models.
• Aggregation theorem suggests that the
representative investor assumption is
typically invalid.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
35
Typical Representative Investor:
Investor Population Heterogeneous
• Violate Bayes rule, even when all
investors are Bayesians.
• Is averse to ambiguity even when no
investor is averse to ambiguity.
• Exhibits stochastic risk aversion even
when all investors exhibit CRRA.
• Exhibits non-exponential discounting
even when all investors exhibit
exponential discounting.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
36
Formally Defining Sentiment 
General Model
Measured by the random variable
 = ln(PR(xt) / (xt)) + ln(R/ R,)
• R, is the R that results when all traders hold
objective beliefs
• Sentiment is not a scalar, but a stochastic
process < , >, involving a log-change of
measure.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
37
Neoclassical Case, Market Efficiency
=0
• The market is efficient when the
representative trader, aggregating the
beliefs of all traders, holds objective
beliefs.
─i.e., efficiency iff PR= 
• When all investors hold objective beliefs
 = (PR/) (R/ R,) = 1
and
 = ln() = 0
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
38
Decomposition of SDF
m  ln(M)
m =  - R ln(g) + ln(R,)
Process <m, >
─Note: In CAPM with market
efficiency, M is linear in g with a
negative coefficient.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
39
Overconfident Bulls &
Underconfident Bears
ln SDF & Sentiment
60.00%
50.00%
40.00%
30.00%
ln(SDF)
20.00%
Sentiment
Function
10.00%
ln(g)
-20.00%
-30.00%
Gross Consumption Growth Rate g
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
40
106.19%
105.82%
105.46%
105.10%
104.74%
104.38%
104.03%
103.67%
103.32%
102.96%
102.61%
102.26%
101.91%
101.56%
101.22%
100.87%
100.53%
100.18%
99.84%
99.50%
99.16%
98.82%
98.48%
98.15%
97.81%
97.48%
97.14%
96.81%
96.48%
96.15%
-10.00%
95.82%
0.00%
How Different is a Behavioural SDF
From a Traditional Neoclassical SDF?
Behavioral SDF vs Traditional SDF
1.2
1.15
Behavioral SDF
1.1
1.05
1
0.95
Traditional Neoclassical SDF
0.9
0.85
Aggregate Consumption Growth Rate g (Gross)
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
41
106%
105%
104%
103%
103%
102%
101%
100%
99%
98%
97%
97%
96%
0.8
It’s Not Risk Aversion in the Aggregate
• Upward sloping portion of SDF is not a
reflection of risk-seeking preferences at
the aggregate level.
• Time varying sentiment  time varying
SDF.
• After 2000, shift to “black swan”
sentiment and by implication SDF.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
42
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
43
Taleb “Black Swan” Sentiment
Overconfidence
Sentiment Function
0.5
-0.5
-1
-1.5
-2
-2.5
Consumption Growth Rate g (Gross)
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
44
106%
104%
103%
101%
99%
97%
96%
0
Barone AdesiEngle-Mancini (2008)
• Empirical SDF based on index options data for
1/2002 – 12/2004.
• Asymmetric volatility and negative skewness
of filtered historical innovations.
• In neoclassical approach, RN density is a
change of measure wrt , thereby “preserving”
objective volatility.
• In behavioral approach RN density is change
of measure wrt PR.
• In BEM, equality broken between physical and
risk neutral volatilities.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
45
SDF for 2002, 2003,
Garch on Left, Gaussian on Right
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
46
Continuous Time Modeling
ln SDF & Sentiment
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
47
50.00%
40.00%
30.00%
ln(SDF)
20.00%
Sentiment
Function
10.00%
106.19%
105.82%
105.46%
105.10%
104.74%
104.38%
104.03%
103.67%
103.32%
102.96%
102.61%
102.26%
101.91%
101.56%
101.22%
100.87%
100.53%
99.84%
100.18%
99.50%
99.16%
98.82%
98.48%
98.15%
97.81%
97.48%
97.14%
96.81%
96.48%
-10.00%
96.15%
0.00%
95.82%
• E(M) is the discount
rate exp(-r) associated
with a risk-free security.
• m=ln(M)
• Take point on realized
sample path, where M
is value of SDF at
current value of g.
• dM has drift –r with
fundamental
disturbance and
sentiment disturbance.
• r>0  expect to move
down the SDF graph.
60.00%
ln(g)
-20.00%
-30.00%
Gross Consumption Growth Rate g
• Fundamental
disturbance relates to
shock to dln(g).
• Sentiment disturbance
relates to shift in
sentiment.
• Marginal optimism
drives E(dm) >0.
Risk Premiums
Risk premium on security Z is the sum
of a fundamental component and a
sentiment component:
-cov[rZ g-]/E[g-] + (fundamental)
ie(1-hZ)/hZ +
(sentiment)
ie-i
(sentiment)
where
hZ = E[ g- rZ]/ E[g- rZ]
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
48
How Different are Returns to a Behavioural
MV-Portfolio From Neoclassical Counterpart?
Gross Return to Mean-variance Portfolio:
Behavioral Mean-Variance Return vs Efficient Mean-Variance Return
110%
105%
Mean-variance Return
100%
Neoclassical Efficient MV Portfolio Return
95%
90%
Behavioral MV Portfolio Return
85%
80%
Consumption Growth Rate g (Gross)
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
49
106%
104%
103%
101%
99%
97%
96%
75%
MV Function  Quadratic
2-factor Model, Mkt and Mkt2
Gross Return to Mean-variance Portfolio:
Behavioral Mean-Variance Return vs Efficient Mean-Variance Return
1.03
1.02
Efficient MV Portfolio Return
Mean-variance Return
1.01
1
0.99
Behavioral MV Portfolio Return
0.98
Return to a Combination of the Market Portfolio and
Risk-free Security
0.97
0.96
Consumption Growth Rate g (Gross)
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
50
106.19%
105.28%
104.38%
103.49%
102.61%
101.74%
100.87%
100.01%
99.16%
98.31%
97.48%
96.64%
95.82%
0.95
When a Coskewness Model
Works Exactly
• The MV return function is quadratic in
g, risk is priced according to a 2-factor
model.
• The factors are g (the market portfolio
return) and g2, whose coefficient
corresponds to co-skewness.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
51
Summary of Key Points
Behaviouralizing Finance
• Paradigm shift.
• Strengths and weaknesses of
behavioural approach.
• Agenda for quantitative finance?
• Combine rigour of neoclassical finance
and the realistic psychologically-based
assumptions of behavioural finance.
Copyright, Hersh Shefrin 2010
52