DUMMY VARIABLES

Download Report

Transcript DUMMY VARIABLES

DUMMY VARIABLES
BY
HARUNA ISSAHAKU
Haruna Issahaku
Definition
• Dummy variables (DV) indicate the presence
or absence of a ‘quality’ or an attribute such
as male or female, black or white, north or
south, etc.
• A dummy variable will take the value 1 or 0
according to whether or not the condition is
present or absent for a particular observation.
Haruna Issahaku
•
•
•
•
1 indicates the presence of the attribute
0 indicates the absence of the attribute
Eg. 1 may represent female and 0 for male
DV are sometimes called categorical variables,
or qualitative variables or indicator variables
• ANOVA MODELS: Used to test the statistical
significance of the relationship between a
quantitative regressand and qualitative or
dummy regressors
Haruna Issahaku
• ANCOVA MODELS: regression models
containing an admixture of quantitative and
dummy regressors.
– They provide a method of statistically controlling
for the effects of quantitative regressors called
covariates or control variables in a model that
includes both quantitative and qualitative
regressors
Haruna Issahaku
A single dummy independent variable
• Given the wage discrimination model
W age  B o   D f  B1 edu  u
• Wage=hourly wage
• D=1 for females and 0 for males
•
• is the difference in hourly wage between males and
females given the same level of education and the same
error term u.
• B o is the mean hourly wage for males (the base or
benchmark group)
•
Haruna Issahaku
Why a single category is included in a
single DV. equation
• Using two DV would introduce perfect colinearity
because for example
• Female + male=1
• Ie. Male is a perfect colinear function of female
• Introducing DV for both male and female is the
simplest example of the so called dummy variable
trap.
• It arises when too many DV describe a given
number of groups
Haruna Issahaku
Overcoming the DV trap
• One way of overcoming the DV trap is to drop
the intercept and include the two categories
• Eg.
W age  B o m ale   fem ale  B1educ .  u
Haruna Issahaku
Some interpretations
•
•
•
•
•
•
Given
Wage = 2.91 - 1.81female + 0.572educ.
Se=
(0.12) (0.26)
(0.049)
N=526
R-sqd=0.364
-males receive a mean wage of Ghc2.91 per hour
-on the average females receive Ghc1.81 less
than their male counterparts holding education
constant.
• -the average hourly wage of female is
• 2.91-1.81=Ghc1.10
Haruna Issahaku
Interpreting coefficients on DV when
an explanatory v. is in log form
• Given the ff. model on the effects of training grants on
hours of training by firms
ˆ p  46.67  26.25 grant  0.98 log( sales )  6.07 log( em ploy )
hrsem
se
 (43.21) (5.59)
(3.54)
(3.54)
n  105
R  0.237
• hrsemp=hours of training per employee at the firm
level
• Grant is a DV =1 if a firm received a job training grant
and 0 otherwise
2
Haruna Issahaku
• Sales=annual sales
• Employ=total no. of employees of the firm
• Grant coefficient of 26.25 means controlling
for sales and employment, firms that receive
grants trained each worker on the average
26.25 hours more
• The coefficient on log sales is small and
insignificant
Haruna Issahaku
• The coefficient on log employ of -6.07 means
• If a firm is 1% larger it trains its workers by
0.061 (ie. 6.07/100) hours less
Haruna Issahaku
Interpreting DV when dependent v. is
in log form
• 1. given the housing price equation
ˆ )  5.56  0.168( lotsize )  0.707 log( sqrft )  0.027 bdrm s  0.054 colonial
log( price
• Colonial is a DV. =1 if house is of a colonial style and 0
otherwise
• Raw interpretation: holding other factors constant the
difference in log(price) of a house of a colonial style is 0.054
• Correct interpretation: a house of the colonial style is predicted
to sell for about 5.4% more, holding other factors constant
• Ie. When the dependent v. is in log form the coefficient on the
DV multiplied by 100 is interpreted as percentage difference in
the dependent variable holding other factors constant.
Haruna Issahaku
2. Given a log hourly wage equation
• Using log(wage) as the dependent v. and adding
quadratics in experience
log( w age )  0.417  0.297 fem ale  0.080 educ  0.029 exp er  0.0005 exp er
• The coefficient on female implies for the same
levels of experience and education women on the
average earn 29.7% (ie. 100*0.297) less than men
• More accurate interpretation: a more accurate
interpretation is obtained by using the formula
Haruna Issahaku
2
• 100*[exp.(B)-1]
• Where B is the coefficient on the dummy
variable
• Thus, 100*[exp.(-0.297)-1]=25.7
• More accurately, on the average a woman’s
wage is 25.7% below a comparable man’s
wage
Haruna Issahaku
• Median hourly wage for males is calculated by
taking the antilog of the intercept 0.417
• exp(0.417)=Ghc1.517
• The median hourly wage of females
• Exp[0.417+(-0.279)]=Ghc1.148
Haruna Issahaku
ANOVA models with 2 DV.
• Model: hourly wage in relation to marital status and
region of residence
Yt 
8.8148 
0.997 D 2 i 
1.6729 D 3 i
se 
(0.4015)
(0.4642)
(0.4854)
t
(21.953)
(2.3688)
(0.0006)
R  0.0322
• Y=hourly wage (Ghc)
• D 2 =marital status 1=married 0=otherwise
• D 3 =region of residence 1=south 0=otherwise
Haruna Issahaku
2
•
•
•
•
Which is the benchmark group?
Unmarried non-south residents
All comparisms are made wrt this group as ff:
-Unmarried non-south residents receive a
mean hourly wage of GhC8.81
• -Those married on average receive Ghc1.10
more than the unmarried non-south residents
Haruna Issahaku
• The mean hourly wage for the married is Ghc
9.91 (ie. 8.81+1.10)
• -the hourly wage of those from the south is
lower by Ghc 1.67
• The mean hourly wage of those from the
south is Ghc7.14 (ie. -1.67+8.81)
• All are statistically significant.
Haruna Issahaku
Interaction effects using DV.
• Given
log( w age )  0.321  0.110 fem ale  0.213 m ale  0.301 fem ale .m arried  u
• Female is a dummy=1 for females; 0=otherwise
• Married is a dummy 1=married 0=otherwise
• The differential effect of being a married female
is 0.301
• Married females earn 35.12% more than single
men with a mode of Ghc1.35
Haruna Issahaku
• What will be the earnings for
– 1. married men?
– 2. single men?
– 3. unmarried females?
Haruna Issahaku
Uses of DV in applied econometric
research
•
•
•
•
•
Read Akoutsoyannis pp.281-284
1. As proxies to qualitative variables
2. As proxies for numerical factors
3. Measuring shifts of a function over time
4. Measuring the change in parameters over
time
• 5. As proxies for the dependent variable
• 6. For seasonal adjustment of time series
Haruna Issahaku
Indicator vs effects coding
• Indicator coding: where the reference category is
assigned zero across the set of DV.
• Effects coding: where the reference category is
assigned a value of negative 1 across the set of DV.
• In indicator coding coefficients represent group
deviations on the dependent variable from the
reference group
• While in effect coding coefficients become group
deviations on the dependent variable from the mean
of the dependent variable across all groups
Haruna Issahaku
Haruna Issahaku
Haruna Issahaku
Haruna Issahaku