Michael Pykhtin

Download Report

Transcript Michael Pykhtin

Pricing Counterparty Credit Risk
at the Trade Level
Michael Pykhtin
Credit Analytics & Methodology
Bank of America
Risk Quant Congress
New York; July 8-9, 2008
Disclaimer
This document is NOT a research report under U.S. law and is NOT a product of a
fixed income research department. Opinions expressed here do not necessarily
represent opinions or practices of Bank of America N.A. The analyses and materials
contained herein are being provided to you without regard to your particular
circumstances, and any decision to purchase or sell a security is made by you
independently without reliance on us. This material is provided for information
purposes only and is not an offer or a solicitation for the purchase or sale of any
financial instrument. Although this information has been obtained from and is based
on sources believed to be reliable, we do not guarantee its accuracy. Neither Bank of
America N.A., Banc Of America Securities LLC nor any officer or employee of Bank
of America Corporation affiliate thereof accepts any liability whatsoever for any
direct, indirect or consequential damages or losses arising from any use of this report
or its contents.
2
Introduction
 Counterparty credit risk is the risk that a counterparty in an
OTC derivative transaction will default prior to the expiration of
the contract and will be unable to make all contractual payments.
– Exchange-traded derivatives bear no counterparty risk.
 The primary feature that distinguishes counterparty risk from
lending risk is the uncertainty of the exposure at any future date.
– Loan: exposure at any future date is the outstanding balance,
which is certain (not taking into account prepayments).
– Derivative: exposure at any future date is the replacement cost, which is
determined by the market value at that date and is, therefore, uncertain.
 For the derivatives whose value can be both positive and
negative (e.g., swaps, forwards), counterparty risk is bilateral.
 See Canabarro & Duffie (2003), De Prisco & Rosen (2005) or
Pykhtin & Zhu (2007).
3
Exposure at Contract Level
 Market value of contract i with a counterparty is known only for
current date t  0. For any future date t, this value Vi (t ) is
uncertain and should be assumed random.
 prior to the contract
maturity, maximum economic loss equals the replacement cost
of the contract
 If the counterparty defaults at time
– If the contract value is positive for us, we do not receive anything from
defaulted counterparty, but have to pay this amount to another
counterparty to replace the contract.
– If the contract value is negative, we receive this amount from another
counterparty, but have to forward it to the defaulted counterparty.
Ei ( )  max[Vi ( ),0]
 Quantity Ei (t ) is known as contract-level exposure at time t
4
Exposure at Counterparty Level
 Counterparty-level exposure at future time t can be defined as
the loss experienced by the bank if the counterparty defaults
at time t under the assumption of no recovery
 If counterparty risk is not mitigated in any way, counterparty-
level exposure equals the sum of contract-level exposures
E (t )   Ei (t )   max[Vi (t ),0]
i
i
 If there are netting agreements, derivatives with positive value
at the time of default offset the ones with negative value within
each netting set NSk , so that counterparty-level exposure is


E (t )   ENSk (t )   max   Vi (t ), 0 
k
k
iNSk

– Each non-nettable trade represents a netting set
5
Credit Value Adjustment (CVA)
 Credit value adjustment is the price of counterparty credit risk.
– See Arvanitis & Gregory (2001), Brigo & Masetti (2005) or
Picoult (2005).
 CVA can be calculated as the risk neutral expectation of the
discounted loss over the life of the longest transaction T
where


B0
CVA  E  1 T  (1  R)
E ( ) 
B


– E(t) is the counterparty-level exposure at time t
6
– 
is the counterparty’s default time
– R
is the counterparty-level recovery rate
– Bt
is the value of the money market account at time t
CVA and Expected Exposure
 Assuming constant recovery rate R, we can write
T
CVA  (1  R)  dP(t ) eˆ(t )
0
where P(t ) is the risk neutral cumulative probability of
default (PD) between today (time 0) and time t
eˆ(t )  E   B0 Bt  E (t )  t 
is risk-neutral discounted expected exposure (EE) at time t
conditional on counterparty defaulting at time t.
 If both exposure and money market account are independent of
counterparty credit state (there is no wrong-way risk), then
eˆ(t )  e(t )  E   B0 Bt  E (t ) 
7
Portfolio Pricing for New Trades
 Suppose, we have a portfolio of derivatives with a counterparty
and we want to add a new trade. How should we price the
counterparty risk for this trade?
 The price of counterparty risk of the new trade is calculated as
the marginal contribution to the portfolio CVA
 CVA Trade  CVA(Portfolio  Trade)  CVA(Portfolio)
 The fair value x of credit risk premium x is calculated from
VTrade( x  x )   CVA Trade( x  x )  VTrade( x 0)
 See Chapter 6 in Arvanitis and Gregory (2001) for details.
8
Allocating CVA to Existing Trades
 CVA is defined and calculated for the entire portfolio. Can we
allocate the counterparty-level CVA to individual trades?
 We need to find allocations CVAi such that they
– reflect trades’ contributions to the counterparty-level CVA
– sum up to the counterparty-level CVA:
CVA   CVAi
i
 Recall that counterparty-level CVA is given by
T
CVA  (1  R)  dP(t ) eˆ(t )
0
 Since both recovery rate R and cumulative PD P(t) are the
same for all trades, CVA allocation reduces to EE allocation!
9
EE Allocation

 For each future time t, we need to find allocations eˆi (t ) such
that they
– reflect trade’s contribution to the counterparty-level discounted EE eˆ(t )
– sum up to the counterparty-level discounted EE: eˆ(t )   eˆi (t )
i
 Allocation across netting sets is trivial because
E (t )   ENSk (t )


eˆ(t )   eˆNS
(t )
k
k
where
k
 B0

eˆNSk (t )  E 
ENSk (t )  t 
 Bt


 We will investigate EE allocation within a netting set
10
Homogeneous Exposure
 For convenience, we will assume that all trades with a
counterparty belong to the same netting set:


E (t )  max  Vi (t ), 0 
 i

 Let us assign a “weight” ai to trade i so that:
Vi (a i , t )  a iVi (t )
 Exposure of an “adjusted” portfolio is


E (a , t )  max  a iVi (t ), 0 
 i

 Therefore, exposure is a homogeneous function of weights:
E(ca , t )  cE(a , t )
11
Definition of EE Contributions

 We define EE contribution eˆi (t ) of trade i at time t as
eˆi(t )  lim
eˆ(t ,1    ui )  eˆ(t ,1)
 0

 eˆ(t ,a )

a i a 1

– eˆ (t , a ) is the counterparty-level EE for portfolio with weights a
– ui describes the portfolio consisting of one unit of trade i
– 1   ui
describes the original portfolio ( ai  1 for all i )
i
 EE contributions sum up to the counterparty-level EE by
Euler’s theorem
 Motivation for this definition comes from allocation of
economic capital for loan portfolios
– see Chapter 4 in Arvanitis and Gregory (2001) for details
12
EE Contributions for Homogeneous Exposure
 Counterparty-level EE is given by
 B0



eˆ (a , t )  E  max a iVi (t ),0    t 
 i

 Bt


 Differentiating with respect to
a i and setting a  1 , we obtain
 B0

eˆi (t )  E  Vi (t ) 1V (t )0   t 
 Bt


where V(t) is the portfolio value given by
V (t )  Vi (t )
i
 These EE contributions sum up to the counterparty-level EE!
13
Non-Homogeneous Exposure
 If there is an exposure-limiting agreement between the bank
and the counterparty (e.g., a margin agreement), exposure is not
a homogeneous function of trades’ weights anymore
 The incremental definition of EE contributions is bound to fail!
– Conditions of Euler’s theorem are not satisfied, and the incremental EE
contributions will not sum up to the counterparty-level EE
 Let us consider a margin agreement and assume that the
portfolio value is above the threshold. Then
– Counterparty-level exposure equals threshold
– Infinitesimal change of the weight of any trade does not change the
counterparty-level exposure
– Therefore, according to the incremental definition, exposure contribution
of any trade is zero!
14
Scenario Approach to EE Contributions
 Let us obtain the EE contributions in an alternative way
 Counterparty-level exposure can be written as

 i Vi (t ) if V (t )  0
E (t )  
otherwise

 0
 It is natural to define stochastic exposure contributions as
Vi (t )
Ei (t )  
 0
if V (t )  0
otherwise
 Applying discounting and conditional expectation, we obtain
 B0

 B0

eˆi (t )  E  Ei (t )   t   E  Vi (t ) 1V (t )0   t 
 Bt

 Bt


15
Margin Agreements
 Let us consider a counterparty with a netting agreement
supported by a margin agreement
 Under a margin agreement, the counterparty must post collateral
C(t) whenever portfolio value exceeds the threshold H :
C (t )  max V (t  )  H ,0
where  is the margin period of risk
 Counterparty-level exposure is given by
E (t )  max V (t )  C (t ),0
 To simplify the model, we will set  = 0
– For liquid trades, typical value of  is 2 weeks, and the error in EE
resulting from setting  = 0 is small
16
Scenario Approach with Margin Agreements
 After setting  = 0 , exposure can be written as
E (t )  10V (t ) H V (t )  1V (t )  H  H
 Let us consider three types of scenarios separately:
– V (t )  0  E (t )  0 : we should set Ei (t )  0
– 0  V (t )  H  E (t )   i Vi (t ) : we should set Ei (t )  Vi (t )
– V (t )  H  E (t )  H : it is reasonable to set Ei (t ) Vi (t ) H V (t )
 Combining all three cases, we obtain exposure contributions
H
Ei (t )  Vi (t )10V (t ) H   Vi (t )
1V (t ) H 
V (t )
17
EE Contributions with Margin Agreements
 Applying discounting and conditional expectation, we obtain
 B0

eˆi (t )  E  Vi (t ) 10V (t ) H    t 
 Bt


 B0

H
 E  Vi (t )
1V (t ) H    t 
V (t )
 Bt

 These EE contributions
– sum up to the counterparty-level EE
– converge to the EE contributions for the non-collateralized case
in the limit H  
18
Calculating EE Contributions
 Let us assume that exposure is independent of the counterparty
credit quality. Then, conditioning on  = t is immaterial.
 The simulation algorithm might look like this:
– Simulate market scenario for simulation time t
– For each trade i, calculate trade value Vi (t)
– Calculate portfolio value V (t )   i Vi (t )
– For each trade i, update its EE contribution counter:
 if 0 < V(t) ≤ H, add Vi (t) B0/Bt
 if V(t) > H, add Vi (t) H /V(t) B0/Bt
 After running large enough number of market scenarios,
divide each EE contribution counter by the number of scenarios
19
Accounting for Wrong/Right-Way Risk
 Let us assume that trade values are dependent on the
counterparty credit quality
– If exposure tends to increase (decrease) when the counterparty credit
quality worsens, the risk is said to be wrong-way (right-way).
 Let us characterize counterparty credit quality by intensity l(t)
 Then, conditional expectation of quantity X can be calculated as
t


1
E  X  t  
E l (t ) exp[  l ( s)ds] X 
P(t ) 
0

where P(t ) is the first derivative of the cumulative PD P(t)
20
Calculating Conditional EE Contributions
 Paths of trade values and of intensity process are simulated jointly
 Assuming that we have already simulated l(tj) for all simulation
times j < k, the simulation algorithm for tk might look like this:
– Simulate market factors and intensity l(tk) for simulation time tk jointly
– For each trade i, calculate trade value Vi (tk)
– Calculate portfolio value V (t )   i Vi (t )
– For each trade i, update the conditional EE contribution counter:
 if 0 < V(t) ≤ H, add
 if V(t) > H, add
21
 k
B
1
l (tk )exp   l (t j 1 )(t j  t j 1 )  0 Vi (tk )
P(tk )
 j 1
 Btk
 k
 B0
1
H
l (tk )exp   l (t j 1 )(t j  t j 1 )  Vi (tk )
P(tk )
V (tk )
 j 1
 Btk
Set-Up for Examples
 If we assume that all trades’ values are normally distributed,
then EE contributions can be evaluated in closed form
 We will look at the EE contribution of trade i of value
Vi (t )  i (t )   i (t ) X i
to portfolio, whose value (not including trade i) is given by
V (t )   (t )   (t ) X
 Correlation between Xi and X is given by ri
 To specify the scale, we set
22
 (t )  1 for the portfolio
No Margin Agreement: Dependence on i
 Parameters:
4
 i  0.05, ri  0
2
1
0
1
2
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
-0.5
-0.4
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
23
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
No Margin Agreement: Dependence on ri
 Parameters:
 i  0.05, i  0
4
2
1
0
0.025
0.020
0.015
0.010
0.005
-1.0
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
0.000
-0.2
0.0
-0.005
-0.010
-0.015
-0.020
-0.025
24
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
Margin Agreement: Dependence on i
 Parameters:
 i  0.05, ri  0,   0.5
H=inf
H=1
H=0.50
H=0.25
H=0.10
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
-0.5
-0.4
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
25
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
Margin Agreement: Dependence on ri
 Parameters:
 i  0.05, i  0,   0.5
H=inf
H=1
H=0.50
H=0.25
H=0.10
0.020
0.015
0.010
0.005
-1.0
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
0.000
-0.2
0.0
-0.005
-0.010
-0.015
-0.020
26
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
Summary
 Discrete marginal approach should be used for pricing
counterparty risk in new trades
 CVA contributions of existing trades to the counterparty-level
CVA can be calculated from the EE contributions
– Continuous marginal approach works when counterparty-level exposure
is homogeneous function of trades’ weights
– Scenario-based approach is needed to handle non-homogeneous cases
(such as margin agreements)
 EE contributions can be easily included in the exposure
simulating process
 Normal approximation gives closed-form results
27
References
 A. Arvanitis and J. Gregory, 2001, “Credit: The Complete Guide to Pricing, Hedging
and Risk Management”, Risk Books
 D. Brigo and M. Masetti, 2005, Risk Neutral Pricing of Counterparty Risk in
“Counterparty Credit Risk Modelling” (M. Pykhtin, ed.), Risk Books
 E. Canabarro and D. Duffie, 2003, Measuring and Marking Counterparty Risk in
“Asset/Liability Management for Financial Institutions” (L. Tilman, ed.), Institutional Investor Books
 B. De Prisco and D. Rosen, 2005, Modelling Stochastic Counterparty Credit Exposures for
Derivatives Portfolios in “Counterparty Credit Risk Modelling” (M. Pykhtin, ed.), Risk Books
 E. Picoult, 2005, Calculating and Hedging Exposure, Credit Value Adjustment and Economic Capital
for Counterparty Credit Risk in “Counterparty Credit Risk Modelling” (M. Pykhtin, ed.), Risk Books
 M. Pykhtin and S. Zhu, 2007, A Guide to Modelling Counterparty Credit Risk
GARP Risk Review, July/August, pages 16-22.
28